Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Endogenous growth and technological progress with innovation driven by social interactions

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze the implications of innovation and social interactions on economic growth in a stylized endogenous growth model with heterogeneous research firms. A large number of research firms decide whether to innovate or not, by taking into account what competitors (i.e., other firms) do. This is due to the fact that their profits partly depend on an externality related to the share of firms which actively engage in research activities. Such a share of innovative firms also determines the evolution of technology in the macroeconomy, which ultimately drives economic growth. We show that when the externality effect is strong enough multiple BGP equilibria may exist. In such a framework, the economy may face a low growth trap suggesting that it may end up in a situation of slow long-run growth; however, such an outcome may be fully solved by government intervention. We also show that whenever multiple BGP exist, they are metastable meaning that the economy may cyclically fluctuate between the low and high BGP as a result of shocks affecting the individual behavior of research firms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Schumpeterian growth models to some extent model the interaction in the research sector by allowing for a business-stealing effect, determining the likelihood that an incumbent innovator loses its monopoly power because of a success in the innovation process by a new entrant (Acemoglu 2009). Apart from this type of characterization, the endogenous growth literature has not emphasized how the choice of research firms are related and interdependent.

  2. This is in line with what suggested by the seminal work by Bass (1969) in the context of diffusion of durables. The Bass model is a particular case of a larger class of epidemiological models. We refer the reader to Hethcote (2000) for a recent survey on the topic.

  3. Few exceptions in which endogenous growth and cyclical fluctuations may be simultaneously experienced exist. Most of these papers focus on an expanding variety model characterized by innovation cycles in which the mechanism underlying economic fluctuations varies from the existence of different investment regimes (Matsuyama 1999, 2001) to international trade and foreign spillovers (Furukawa 2015). Others focus instead on the mutual relation between human capital investments and productivity growth (Kaas and Zink 2007). Our approach is substantially different since we rely on a simple capital accumulation model in which the evolution of the total factor productivity is the result of firms’ interactions within the research industry.

  4. Cyclical outcomes are also analyzed in growth theory by characterizing the eventual existence of equilibrium indeterminacy (Benhabib and Farmer 1994; Benhabib and Nishimura 1998; Lahiri 2001). Also this approach is substantially different from ours, since our BGP equilibria are all determinate and are due to the presence of noisy components affecting the research industry costs.

  5. Because of the similarity with our paper and their qualitative results, the seminal work by Evans et al. (1998) deserves some specific comments. Indeed, also Evans et al. (1998) show that under specific conditions a stylized economic growth model may give rise to a low growth trap and a growth cycle in which the economy stochastically switches between periods of low and high growth. However, the underlying argument and the type of dynamics at the basis of their analysis is substantially different from ours, since, apart from relying on a discrete-time setup, the driver of the entire economic dynamics in their model is represented by shocks on agents’ expectations which affect the learning dynamics associated with multiple perfect-foresight equilibria. Our results, instead, are derived in a micro-founded model where firm-specific shocks within the research industry, by determining the evolution of technology, propagate in the whole economy eventually generating growth cycles; the concept of endogenous fluctuations we describe is thus not related to either expectational indeterminacy or self-fulfilling growth cycles, which represent the traditional mechanisms discussed in the business cycle literature (Evans et al. 1998; Furukawa 2007). The fact that such very different setups allow to generate qualitatively similar dynamics suggests that endogenous growth cycles and low growth traps are not only rare theoretical possibility but rather outcomes quite common whenever we depart from the traditional economic growth framework.

  6. Despite the existence of some (absolute) convergence within a small number of industrialized countries (see, for example, Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995), convergence clubs represent more the exception rather than the rule in the empirics of economic growth.

  7. For the time being, we do not look at the demand side of the innovation market, but this will be introduced in a very stylized way in Sect. 3, where we assume that the government buys such an innovation. The amount of revenue h can thus be interpreted as the incentive provided by the government to induce firms to perform research activities, or alternatively as the price at which it purchases the innovation from research firms.

  8. This externality in research profits may be interpreted in terms of the availability of potential trading partners for the innovation, which reflects into a larger or smaller willingness to produce according to the sign of J in (1). With this respect, the market for innovation is similar to the trading market proposed in Diamond (1982).

  9. We could in principle use any continuous probability distribution. The logistic is vastly used in the context of random utility models. One reason being that the dynamics obtained under this assumption have a logistic shape which seems to represent patterns underlying many social phenomena (see Anderson et al. 1992).

  10. We provide here a straightforward proof based on the argument developed in Blume and Durlauf (2003). A more detailed and alternative proof of the law of large numbers will be provided in Sect. 6 in a more general setting. Note that in that case, we can only provide a weak convergence result, being the proof based on the convergence of generators of the underlying Markov processes.

  11. Note that since household size is constant, in our model the difference between welfare as defined according to either the average or total utilitarian criterion is simply a constant, equal to household size (see Marsiglio 2014 for a recent discussion of the implications of average and total utilitarianism on economic growth). However, since the size of household is assumed infinitely large (why this is needed will become clear later), we cannot rely on total utilitarianism since this would imply that household’s objective function is infinite.

  12. Note that in the research firms’ profit structure (1), only the constant term h appears. We, in fact, use a “per unit” measure of (perceived) profit \(h=\tilde{h}_t/y_t\). Such a measure is more appropriate to study firms interaction since \(\tilde{h}_t\) diverges to infinity over time exactly as \(y_t\). Although still tractable (see Example 2), the formulation with the “non-discounted” \(\tilde{h}_t\) turns out to be trivial and thus less interesting, since the private profit component (related to \(\tilde{h}_t\)) is not comparable with the social component (which is bounded). See Sect. 6, where we provide some examples related to the more general case of a time-varying \(h_t\), including also the non-discounted \(\tilde{h}_t\) case.

  13. An increase in the number of firms in the research industry does not rise the overall economic growth rate. This rate can increase only if the equilibrium share of innovative firms rises.

  14. Note that the eventual multiplicity in the equilibrium of the innovation share is due to the heterogeneity in research firms. As more specifically discussed in “Appendix 1,” in the case of homogeneous research firms the equilibrium innovation share will necessarily be unique and equal to either zero or one, meaning that the BGP growth rate will be either null or maximal, respectively. Such an outcome is clearly possible but also trivial; thus, in our discussion we focus only on the most interesting case in which research firms are heterogeneous.

  15. Note that the intermediate equilibrium \(\gamma _M\), although saddle-point stable, is derived from an innovation share \(\overline{x}_M\) which is linearly unstable on its own. Therefore, unless we assume that the economy is exactly tuned on \(x_0=\bar{x}_M\), this equilibrium will never emerge. For this reason, we will not consider it as a possible realist economic outcome.

  16. The importance of the initial share of innovative firms for the model’s outcome is further discussed in Sect. 5 where we focus on the finite-number of research firms case. We will show that in such a (stochastic) framework the presence of multiple equilibria might give rise to growth cycles.

  17. When a unique equilibrium exists, the finite dimensional system is still stable in the sense that shocks generate fluctuations around the unique equilibrium. In this case, the long timescale effect is not present since there is no possibility of cycling between equilibria. We thus focus our discussion in this section on the most interesting case in which multiple equilibria exist and the implications of metastability.

  18. We would like to stress the fact that, as mentioned earlier, such a metastable behavior pertains also to the finite dimensional version of classical random utility models such as the Brock and Durlauf (2001) model. To the best of our knowledge, such a peculiarity of this type of systems has never been discussed within the economics literature.

  19. We are indebted to an anonymous referee for suggesting such a non-trivial model’s extension. Apart from generalizing our previous results, this allows us to discuss the mathematics behind this formulation with endogenous \(h_t=H(\cdot )\) and compare it with the classical random utility model with constant h. To the best of our knowledge, such a type of generalization has never been discussed in the literature thus far, not even in other frameworks.

  20. The term “middle-income trap” has been originally introduced by Gill and Kharas (2007), and the notion has also often been referred to as “growth slowdown” (Eichengreen et al. 2012).

  21. In statistical mechanics, the Gibbs free energy characterizes the potential associated with the states of the system. In particular, it can be proved that the equilibria \(m_L\) and \(m_H\) are local minimum points for f, whereas \(m_M\) is a local maximum point.

References

  • Agénor, P.R., Canuto, O.: Middle-income growth traps. Res. Econ. 69, 641–660 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C., Stachurski, J.: Poverty traps. In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (eds.) Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, Chap. 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2005)

  • Acemoglu, D.: Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Howitt, P.: A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60, 323–351 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S., De Palma, A., Thisse, J.-F.: Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. MIT Press, Cambridge (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bambi, M., Gozzi, F., Licandro, O.: Endogenous growth and wave-like business fluctuations. J. Econ. Theory 154, 68–111 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J., Sala-i-Martin, X.: Economic Growth. Cambridge, MIT Press (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bass, F.M.: A new product growth for model consumer durables. Manage. Sci. 15, 215–227 (1969)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barucci, E., Tolotti, M.: Social interaction and conformism in a random utility model. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 36, 1855–1866 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Farmer, R.: Indeterminacy and increasing returns. J. Econ. Theory 63, 19–41 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Nishimura, K.: Indeterminacy and sunspots with constant returns. J. Econ. Theory 81, 58–96 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., Durlauf, S.: Equilibrium concepts for social interaction models. Int. Game Theory Rev. 5, 193–209 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W., Durlauf, S.: Discrete choice with social interactions. Rev. Econ. Stud. 68, 235–260 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canton, E.: Business cycles in a two-sector model of endogenous growth. Econ. Theor. 19, 477–492 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commission on Growth and Development: The growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. World Bank, Washington DC (2008)

  • Dawid, H.: Agent-based models of innovation and technological change. In: Tesfatsion, L., Judd, K.L. (eds.) Handbook of Computational Economics, vol. 2, pp. 1235–1272. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P.A.: Aggregate demand management in search equilibrium. J. Polit. Econ. 90, 881–894 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., Roventini, A.: Schumpeter meeting Keynes: a policy-friendly model of endogenous growth and business cycles. J. Econ. Dyn. Control l34, 1748–1767 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dowrick, S.: Technological catch up and diverging incomes: patterns of economic growth 1960–88. Econ. J. 102, 600–610 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., Park, D., Shin, K.: When fast economies slow down: international evidence and implications for China. Asian Econ. Papers 11, 42–87 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., Park, D., Shin, K.: Growth Slowdowns Redux: New Evidence on the Middle-income Trap, Working Paper No. 18673, National Bureau of Economic Research (2013)

  • Ethier, S.N., Kurtz, T.G.: Markov Processes: Characterization and Convergence. Wiley, New York (1986)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G.W., Honkapohja, S., Romer, P.: Growth cycles. Am. Econ. Rev. 88, 495–515 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Furukawa, Y.: Endogenous growth cycles. J. Econ. 91, 69–96 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furukawa, Y.: Leapfrogging cycles in international competition. Econ. Theor. 59, 401–433 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, I., Kharas, H.: An East Asian Renaissance: Ideas for Economic Growth. World Bank, Washington, DC (2007)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E.: Endogenous innovation in the theory of growth. J. Econ. Perspect. 8, 23–44 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hethcote, H.W.: The mathematics of infectious diseases. SIAM Rev. 42, 599–653 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C.I.: Growth and ideas. In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (eds.) Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1B, pp. 1063–1111. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaas, L., Zink, S.: Human capital and growth cycles. Econ. Theor. 31, 19–33 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F., Prescott, E.: Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50, 1345–1370 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, R., Plosser, C.I., Rebelo, S.T.: Production, growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model. J. Monet. Econ. 21, 195–232 (1988)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, R., Plosser, C.I., Rebelo, S.T.: Production, growth and business cycles: II. New directions. J. Monet. Econ. 21, 309–0341 (1988)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri, A.: Growth and equilibrium indeterminacy: the role of capital mobility. Econ. Theor. 17, 197–208 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Torre, D., Liuzzi, D., Marsiglio, S.: Pollution diffusion and abatement activities across space and over time. Math. Social Sci. 78, 48–63 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, A.W.: Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. Manchester School 22, 139–191 (1954)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathieu, P., Picco, P.: Metastability and convergence to equilibrium for the random field Curie–Weiss model. J. Stat. Phys. 91, 679–732 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marchese, C., Marsiglio, S., Privileggi, F., Ramello G.B.: Endogenous Recombinant Growth Through Market Production of Knowledge and Intellectual Property Rights. Dip. Cognetti de Martiis, Working Paper No. 13/2014 (2014)

  • Marsiglio, S.: Reassessing Edgeworth’s conjecture when population dynamics is stochastic. J. Macroecon. 42, 130–140 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama, K.: Growing through cycles. Econometrica 67, 335–347 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama, K.: Growing through cycles in an infinitely lived agent economy. J. Econ. Theory 100, 220–234 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazzucato, M.: The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector Myths. Anthem Press, Cambridge (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mullingan, C.B., Sala-i-Martin, X.: Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. Quart. J. Econ. 108, 739–773 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R.R., Winter, S.G.: An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Belknap Press, Cambridge (1982)

    Google Scholar 

  • Olivieri, R., Vares, M.E.: Large Deviations and Metastability, Encyclopedia of Mathematics and its Applications, vol. 100. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2005)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett, L.: Divergence, big time. J. Econ. Perspect. 11, 3–17 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P.: Increasing returns and long-run growth. J. Polit. Econ. 94, 1002–1037 (1986)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J.D., McArthur, J.W., Schimdt-Traub, G., Kruk, M., Bahadur, C., Faye, M., McCord, G.: Ending Africa’s Poverty Trap, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1. The Brookings Institution, Washington (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, W.T.: A closed form solution to the Ramsey model. Contributions to Macroeconomics 6, Article 3 (2006)

  • Skiba, A.K.: Optimal growth with a convex–concave production function. Econometrica 46, 527–539 (1978)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walde, K.: Endogenous growth cycles. Int. Econ. Rev. 46, 867–894 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xie, D.: Divergence in economic performance: transitional dynamics with multiple equilibria. J. Econ. Theory 63, 97–112 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are indebted to two anonymous referees for their constructive comments helping us to substantially improve our paper. We also acknowledge the financial support from MIUR under grant “Robust decision making in markets and organizations” (PRIN20103S5RN3) and the support from Ca’ Foscari University Venice under the grant “Interactions in complex economic systems: contagion, innovation and crises”.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marco Tolotti.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The rationale behind random utility models

In this appendix, we briefly summarize the main ideas recovered by Brock and Durlauf (2001) and leading to the profit structure defined in (1). Suppose that a research firm faces the binary decision to innovate or not to innovate. We define the binary random variable \(\omega \in \{0,1\}\) accordingly. The main assumption behind random utility models is that the profit \(\pi \) related to the innovation has the following general structure:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi (\omega _i)=R(\omega _i, \mu _i^e(\omega _{-i}), h)-\zeta (\omega _i), \end{aligned}$$

where revenues R depend on the choice made by the firm, on the price h received by the buyer of the innovation and by an externality term. Indeed, each firm i estimates the conditional probability measure \(\mu _i^e\) on the choices of others, where \(\omega _{-i}\) denotes the vector of actions deprived of the i-th component. As seen in Sect. 2, costs are random and denoted by \(\zeta \). For the moment, we set \(z=0\) for simplicity.

We now make some further (minimal) assumptions to came up with a tractable profit structure.

  1. (i)

    \(\pi (0)=0\). This is an obvious normalization. Both R and \(\zeta \) are zero if no research activity is in place. Therefore, we concentrate on \(\pi (1)\) (we call it simply \(\pi \)). Rearranging variables and notations, we have:

    $$\begin{aligned} \pi =R( \mu _i^e(\omega _{-i}), h)-\zeta _i. \end{aligned}$$
  2. (ii)

    Externalities due to the behavior of competitors only depend on the average action of others’ choice. This implies that \(\mu _i^e(\omega _{-i})\) is substituted by the (simpler) statistics \(x_i^e=\frac{1}{N-1}\sum _{j\ne i} x_{ij}^e\), where \(x_{ij}^e={\mathbb {E}}^{(i)}[\omega _j]\) denotes the expectation of firm i about the choice of competitor j. Therefore,

    $$\begin{aligned} \pi =R(x_i^e, h)-\zeta _i. \end{aligned}$$

    Concerning the information structure of the model, we also assume that \({\mathbb {E}}^{(i)}[\cdot ]={\mathbb {E}}^{(j)}[\cdot ]\) for all \(i,j=1,\dots , N\). This amounts in saying that all firms share the same expectations about others’ choices.

  3. (iii)

    We assume that \(\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial x^e_i}=J\). This simplifying assumption introduces a unique parameter J measuring the degree of dependence (or the force of externality) due to the others’ actions. Note that \(J>0\) resembles a staying-on-the-shoulder situation, whereas \(J<0\) a fishing-out case. Secondly, as obvious, \(\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial h}>0\).

  4. (iv)

    We assume that the pecuniary effects due to the sale of the technology and the externalities are additive. Moreover, for sake of simplicity, we assume a linear dependence. This fact, together with assumption iii), produces the following payoff:

    $$\begin{aligned} \pi =h+J x_i^e-\zeta _i. \end{aligned}$$
  5. (v)

    Finally, we slightly correct \(x^e_i\) by substituting it with \(x^e_i-\frac{1}{2}\). The reason is that we want the decision to be driven by what the majority of the population of firms is doing. The quantity \(x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\) reflects exactly this goal: it is positive if and only if the majority of the research firms produces an innovation. Therefore, in case of a positive J, the single firm is more prone to align with the majority. On the contrary, if \(J<0\), the firm will tend to behave in the opposite direction. We obtain:

    $$\begin{aligned} \pi =h-\zeta _i+J \, \left( x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, by reintroducing a private cost z and recalling that \(\pi (0)=0\), we obtain the general expression for \(\pi \) as it appears in (1):

$$\begin{aligned} \pi (\omega _i)=\omega _i \left[ h-(z+\zeta _i)+ J\left( x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

By applying the payoff structure defined above, we can verify that

$$\begin{aligned} \omega _i=1 \, \iff \, \pi (1)\ge \pi (0) \, \iff \, h-(z+\zeta _i)+ J\left( x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\right) \ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

The probabilistic structure of the model implies that for all \(i=1,\dots , N\),

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {P}}(\omega _i=1)= & {} {\mathbb {P}} \left( h-(z+\zeta _i)+ J\left( x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\right) \ge 0\right) \\= & {} {\mathbb {P}} \left( \zeta _i \le h-z+ J\left( x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\right) \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Since agents receive different private signals, agents may have a different feeling about the best choice. Heterogeneity gives rise to the non-trivial equilibria and the (possible) multiplicity discussed in Proposition 2. In the case of a completely deterministic model (i.e., \(\zeta _i=0\) for all i), agents would be homogeneous and we would obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {P}} \left( 0 \le h-z+ J\left( x_i^e-\frac{1}{2}\right) \right) \in \{0;1\}, \end{aligned}$$

meaning that either \(\omega _i=0\) or \(\omega _i=1\) for all \(i=1,\dots ,N\). The same reasoning extends to the continuous-time counterpart described by (4): assuming no randomness, there would be no space for any dynamics, and the outcome would be to a large extent trivial with all firms deciding either to innovate or not to innovate. In the body of the paper, we thus focus on the most interesting situation in which agent heterogeneity gives rises to non-trivial dynamics. Most of our qualitative results in Proposition 2 would still hold true in the absence of heterogeneity case, but in this case the BGP equilibrium would be necessarily unique and characterized by either one of the two extreme long-run growth rates \(\gamma =\frac{\phi }{1-\alpha }\) if \(\overline{x}=1\) or \(\gamma =0\) if \(\overline{x}=0\).

Appendix 2: Proof of Proposition 3

The proof of Proposition 3 basically follows Theorem 4.6 in Olivieri and Vares (2005). In order to make this reading as much self-consistent as possible, we sketch the proof rearranged to match our model and our notations. We firstly specify the functional form for \(\varDelta \). To this aim, we introduce the so-called Gibbs free energy:Footnote 21

$$\begin{aligned} f_{\beta ,J,h}(m)=-\left( \frac{J}{4}m^2+{hm} \right) + \frac{1}{\beta }\cdot \varepsilon (m), \end{aligned}$$
(35)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon (m)=\frac{1+m}{2}\ln \left( \frac{1+m}{2}\right) +\frac{1-m}{2}\ln \left( \frac{1-m}{2}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Finally, define

$$\begin{aligned} \varDelta =\beta \,\left( f(m_M)-f(m_L) \right) \end{aligned}$$

where f is as defined in (35), \(m_M=2\bar{x}_M-1\) and \(m_L=2\bar{x}_L-1\) and where \(\bar{x}_L\) and \(\bar{x}_M\) are, respectively, the smallest and the middle solutions (recall that, under our assumptions on the values of the parameters, this equation admits three real solutions \(\bar{x}_L<\bar{x}_M<\bar{x}_H\)) to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{2}\,\tanh \left\{ \beta \left[ h-z+J\left( x_t-\frac{1}{2}\right) \right] \right\} -x_t+\frac{1}{2}=0. \end{aligned}$$

In what follows, we organize the proof Proposition 3 into four steps. In the first step, we provide a lower bound for \(T_N\), in the second an upper bound. Finally, we prove part (a) and part (b) of the proposition. As said, we only sketch the main results and refer the reader to Olivieri and Vares (2005) for further details. Our aim is mainly to let the reader appreciate the probabilistic properties, which this proposition relies on.

  1. (i)

    There exists a positive constant \(c_1\) such that, for N large enough \(\bar{,}\) and each positive integer T,

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {P}}(T_N\le T)\le c_1 T e^{-N\varDelta }. \end{aligned}$$
    (36)

    This fact follows from the properties of the stationary distribution of a Markov chain. Indeed, let us define the stationary measure of \((x^N_t)_{t\ge 0}\) as \(\nu _N\). It can be proved that

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {P}}(T_N\le T)\le T \cdot \frac{\nu _N(x_M^N)}{\nu _N(x_L^N)}=T\cdot e^{-N\beta (f(m_M)-f(m_L))}. \end{aligned}$$

    On the other hand, for N large enough, \(\beta \, f(m_M)-f(m_L)\ge \varDelta -\frac{c_2}{N}\) for a suitable constant \(c_2\). Therefore, (36) easily follows by putting \(c_1=e^{c_2}\).

  2. (ii)

    For any positive sequence \((\varphi _N)_{N\ge 1}\) such that \(\varphi _N \rightarrow \infty \),

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {P}}(T_N\ge e^{N\varDelta } N \varphi _N )=0. \end{aligned}$$
    (37)

    This follows from the fact that, for suitable constants \(c_3\) and \(c_4\),

    $$\begin{aligned} c_3 e^{N\varDelta } \le {\mathbb {E}}(T_N)\le c_4 N^2 e^{N\varDelta }. \end{aligned}$$
    (38)

    For details on the proof of (38), we refer to Corollary 4.9 in Olivieri and Vares (2005). From (38) and applying the Markov inequality, we obtain (37).

  3. (iii)

    Point (a) of Proposition 3 follows from the fact that

    $$\begin{aligned}&1-{\mathbb {P}}\left( \frac{1}{\varphi _N} e^{N\varDelta }< T_N<e^{N\varDelta } N \varphi _N \right) \nonumber \\&\quad ={\mathbb {P}}\left( T_N\le \frac{1}{\varphi _N}e^{N\varDelta }\right) +{\mathbb {P}}\left( T_N\ge e^{N\varDelta } N \varphi _N \right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Both terms of the RHS go to zero for any positive sequence \((\varphi _N)_{N\ge 1}\) such that \(\varphi _N\rightarrow \infty \) due to (i) and (ii), respectively. This proves part (a) in Proposition 3.

  4. (iv)

    Define the sequence of random variables \((\tilde{T}_N)_{N\ge 2}\), where \(\tilde{T}_N{:=}\,T_N/\gamma _N\) and where \(\gamma _N\) is such that

    $$\begin{aligned} \lim _{N \rightarrow \infty } N^{-1}\ln ( \gamma _N)=\varDelta . \end{aligned}$$

    It can be shown that this sequence is tight and its limits \(\tau \) along subsequences have the property that

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {P}}(\tau>t+s)={\mathbb {P}}(\tau>t)\,{\mathbb {P}}(\tau >s). \end{aligned}$$

    This, in turns, shows that \(\tilde{T}_N\) is asymptotically exponential, thus, memoryless. Finally,

    $$\begin{aligned} \lim _{N\rightarrow \infty } {\mathbb {E}} [\tilde{T}_N] =\int _0^{+\infty } \lim _{N\rightarrow \infty } {\mathbb {P}}(T_N>s\, \gamma _N) \, ds=\int _0^{+\infty }e^{-s}ds=1\,, \end{aligned}$$

    and this concludes the proof of Proposition 3. To be precise, what we have shown in point iv) is true for a stopped version of \(x^N\): consider \(\tilde{x}^N\) where \(\tilde{x}^N_t\) has the same transition probabilities of \(x^N_t\) for \(t\le T_N\) and \(\tilde{x}^N_t\equiv \tilde{x}^N_{T_N}\) for \(t\ge T_N\) (it is a stopped version of the original process at time \(T_N\)). It can be proved that the two processes are coupled up to \(T_N\), so that the their probabilistic features are the same. Since we are interested in the trajectories up to \(T_N\), working with \(x^N\) or \(\tilde{x}^N\) is exactly the same to our purposes. \(\square \)

Note, finally, that the transition from \(\bar{x}_L\) to \(\bar{x}_H\) can be analyzed exactly in the same way, by simply considering \(\varDelta =\beta \,\left( f(m_M)-f(m_H) \right) \). We would like to stress the fact that, differently from the common notion of cycles in macroeconomics in which their periodicity is highly irregular and stochastic, in probability theory the notion of cycles requires the periods of the transitions to be deterministic and constant. According to this latter view, the tunneling time \(T_N\) should converge to 1, rather that to an exponential random time with average 1 as stated in Proposition 3. Therefore, even if this is not totally correct from a probabilistic point of view, in our discussion we adopt the macroeconomic view and terminology by referring to the metastability property as a cycling behavior.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Marsiglio, S., Tolotti, M. Endogenous growth and technological progress with innovation driven by social interactions. Econ Theory 65, 293–328 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-1017-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-1017-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation