Skip to main content
Log in

Mean–variance efficient large portfolios: a simple machine learning heuristic technique based on the two-fund separation theorem

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We revisit in this article the Two-Fund Separation Theorem as a simple technique for the Mean–Variance optimization of large portfolios. The proposed approach is fast and scalable and provides equivalent results of commonly used ML techniques but, with computing time differences counted in hours (1 min vs. several hours). In the empirical application, we consider three geographic areas (China, US, and French stock markets) and show that the Two-Fund Separation Theorem holds exactly when no constraints are imposed and is approximately true with (realistic) positive constraints on weights. This technique is shown to be of interest to both scholars and practitioners involved in portfolio optimization tasks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Wind; daily quotes of the 40 largest companies that are part of the CSI300, from 08/18/2008 to 12/31/2019. Plotted are: the Unconstrained Efficient Frontier, the capital market line (CML) and some notorious portfolios (V, N, T, C, G and G′). Computations by the authors

Fig. 2

Source: Wind; daily quotes of the 40 largest companies that are part of the CSI300, from 08/18/2008 to 12/31/2019. Plotted are: the Unconstrained Efficient Frontier, the Capital Market Line (CML) and some notorious portfolios (A, T, and BJ). Computations by the authors

Fig. 3

Source: Wind; daily quotes of the 40 largest companies that are part of the CSI300, from 08/18/2008 to 12/31/2019. Plotted are: the Unconstrained Efficient Frontier, the Efficient Frontier by Penalized Regression with low and high penalization, the Positively Constrained LASSO Efficient Frontier, the Positively Constrained Efficient Frontier by TFST, the capital market line (CML) and some notorious portfolios (\(T\), \(MAX\), \(N\), and \(V\) ), where a portfolio distinguished by a superscript “*” denotes the corresponding portfolio under positivity constraint. TFST corresponds to Two-Fund Separation Theorem, which is to build Efficient Frontiers by the combination of two pivotal portfolios: the Positively Constrained Global Minimum-Variance Portfolio (\(V\)) and the Asset with the Highest Expected Return or four pivotal portfolios: the Positively Constrained Global Minimum-Variance Portfolio, the Positively Constrained Null Index Portfolio, the Positively Constrained Tangent Portfolio and the Asset with the Highest Expected Return. Computations by the authors

Fig. 4

Source: Wind; daily quotes of the 40 largest companies that are part of the CSI300, from 08/18/2008 to 12/31/2019. Plotted are: the capital market line (CML), the Unconstrained Efficient Frontier, the Positively Constrained LASSO Efficient Frontier, the Positively Constrained Efficient Frontier by TFST with Two Pivotal Portfolios, the Positively Constrained Efficient Frontier with Four Pivotal Portfolios and some notorious portfolios (\(A\), \(MAX\), \(V\), \(T\), \(G\), \(G^{\prime}\), \(N\), \(BJ\), \(EWI\), and \(CWI\)), where EWI is an Equally-Weighted Index Portfolio and CWI is a Capitalization-Weighted Index Portfolio. A portfolio distinguished by a superscript “*” denotes the corresponding portfolio under positivity constraint. TFST corresponds to Two-Fund Separation Theorem, which is to build Efficient Frontiers by the combination of two pivotal portfolios: the Positively Constrained Global Minimum-Variance Portfolio and the Asset with the Highest Expected Return (in the blue bold line) or four pivotal portfolios (in the blue dotted bold line): the Positively Constrained Global Minimum-Variance Portfolio, the Positively Constrained Null Index Portfolio, the Positively Constrained Tangent Portfolio and the Asset with the Highest Expected Return. Computations by the authors

Fig. 5

Source: Wind; daily quotes of the 40 largest companies that are part of the CSI300, from 08/18/2008 to 12/31/2019. Plotted are: the 5%-, 50%- and 95%-quantile of the double block-bootstrapped resampled LASSO Efficient Frontier and the corresponding 50%-quantile of the Efficient Frontier by TFST. Resampled Efficient Frontiers are computed by using a double-block bootstrap method (see Michaud, 1989; Michaud & Michaud, 2008; Ledoit & Wolf, 2008, 2011) both on dates and sub-samples of stocks. TFST corresponds to Two-Fund Separation Theorem, which is used to build the Efficient Frontier by combinations of two pivotal portfolios, namely the Global Minimum-Variance Portfolio and the Asset with the Highest Expected Return. Computations by the authors

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Markowitz (1959), Sharpe (1964), Mossin (1966), Lintner (1965a, 1965b), Black (1972), as well as Dybvig and Liu (2018), and further adaptations of the original Separation Theorem when agents do not exhibit Mean–Variance preferences or when the densities of return are not Gaussian, as in Pye (1967), Hakansson (1969), Cass and Stiglitz (1970), Harvey and Siddique (2000), Jurczenko and Maillet (2006), Dahlquist et al. (2017), or in a continuous-time stochastic setting, as in Samuelson (1967), Merton (1973), Ross (1978), and more recently in Cairns et al. (2006), Deguest et al. (2018) and Bernard et al. (2021).

  2. We will adopt hereafter the presentation and (very similar) notations used in both of these books.

  3. For the sake of simplicity and clarification, each time we have a vector of 1 with dimensions \(\left( {N \times 1} \right)\) with \(N\) being the number of the assets, we use: \({\mathbf{1}}: = {\mathbf{1}}_{{\left( {N \times 1} \right)}}\) as a notation, whilst for a vector of 1 with dimensions \(\left( {T \times 1} \right)\), with \(T\) being the number of dates of the time-series of returns on an asset, we denote it as: \({\mathbf{1}}_{{\left( {T \times 1} \right)}}\). When we will need a \(\left( {N \times N} \right)\) matrix of 1, we will further denote it: \({\mathbf{1}}_{{\left( {N \times N} \right)}}\).

  4. See, for instance, Black and Litterman (1992) for an alternative approach with deformed expectations according to views in a Bayesian context.

  5. See Mahalanobis (1927, 1936); see also Mardia et al. (1979), Meucci (2009), Breuer et al. (2009), Breuer and Csiszár (2013), Geyer et al. (2014), Flood and Korenko (2015), McNeil et al. (2015) and De Meo (2021) for other uses of the Mahalanobis norm in financial applications.

  6. Here we follow Huang and Litzenberger (1988, p. 64) with \(A = a\), \(B = b\), \(C = c\), \(D = d\), whilst Ingersoll (1987) p. 54 uses \(B = a\), \(C = b\), \(A = c\), and \(\Delta { } = d\).

  7. Furthermore, it is not equal to zero, and positive in our financial applications—see the Online Appendix, which allows us to use the term \(d\) in some denominators below, with no risk of indetermination.

  8. We will use later on, similarly, the notations \({\mathcal{F}}^{*}\), \({\overline{\mathcal{F}}}^{*}\) and \({\underline {\mathcal{F}} }^{*}\) for the same defined sets in a constrained context.

  9. See also Gouriéroux and Jouneau (1999) for a discussion about fitted performance measures.

  10. Such as: \(S_{p} = \left[ {E(R_{p} ) - R_{f} } \right]/\sigma (R_{p} )\), with \(R_{f} \) the risk-free rate.

  11. Cf. Ingersoll (1987, p. 56) and Huang and Litzenberger (1988, p. 66).

  12. See also Corollary 2.1 in the Online Appendix A-4, when inversing the problem and setting first the targeted expected return (for Asset-Liability Management reasons for instance), we deduce the optimal related Efficient Portfolio and its linked implicit risk and just vice-versa in the Corollary 2.2 (see the Online Appendix A-5). Corollary 2.3 (see in the Online Appendix A-6) also interestingly illustrates the proper structure of some notorious Portfolios according to Proposition 2, with explicit parameters.

  13. With \(E\left( {R_{C} } \right) = a/c\) and \(\sigma \left( {R_{C} } \right) = 0\), and the two asymptotes follow a relation as such: \(E\left( {R_{p} } \right) = a/c \pm \sqrt {d/c } \sigma \left( {R_{p} } \right)\)—see A-9 for details in the Online Appendix.

  14. Similarly, Black (1972) proves that every efficient portfolio can be generated by two arbitrary portfolios \(u\) and \(v\), with \(\beta_{u} = 1\) and \(\beta_{v} = 0\), where \(\beta_{u}\) and \(\beta_{v}\) are measuring the volatility of an individual stock compared to the systematic risk.

  15. Or, exceptionally, on \({\overline{\mathcal{F}}}\), if the GMVP expected return is negative.

  16. See also Broadie (1993), Kempf and Memmel (2006) and the Online Appendix for their approach, and Stevens (1998) who proves that elements of \({{\varvec{\Omega}}}^{ - 1}\) are: \({{\varvec{\Omega}}}^{ - 1}_{ij} = { }\left( { - 1} \right)^{o} \times \left[ {{\upsigma }_{ii} \left( {1 - R_{i}^{2} } \right)} \right]^{ - 1} \beta_{ij}^{{}} ,\) where \({{\varvec{\Omega}}}^{ - 1}_{ij}\) is the element on the ith row and jth column of \({{\varvec{\Omega}}}^{ - 1}\), coefficient o is equal to 0 if \(j = i\) and 1 otherwise, \({\upsigma }_{ii}\) the variance of returns on the ith asset, \(\beta_{ij}^{{}}\) the sensitivities (i.e. regression coefficients) for the regression of the return of the ith asset on those of all other N–1 assets and \(R_{i}^{2}\) the multiple regression coefficient (i.e. coefficient of determination) for the same regression. As expected, we find in the hereafter empirical studies that direct estimates of the inverse Variance–CoVariance matrix, denoted \({\hat{\mathbf{\Omega }}}^{ - 1}\) (both in the unconstrained and constrained cases), correspond to the one defined according to the regression method by Stevens (1998)—See A-9 in the Online Appendix.

  17. Where, following the notations by Hastie et al. (2015), the \(\ell_{2}\)-norm is such as: \(\left\| {{\mathbf{1}}\overline{\mu }_{p} - {\mathbf{Xw}}_{p} } \right\|_{2} = \left\| {\varvec{u}} \right\|_{2} = (\mathop \sum \limits_{{t = \left[ {1, \ldots ,T} \right]}} \left| {u_{t} } \right|^{2} )^{1/2}\), where \(u_{t}\) is the tth element of the vector of residuals denoted \({\varvec{u}} = \left( {{\mathbf{1}}\overline{\mu }_{p} - {\mathbf{Xw}}_{p} } \right)\), and with \(\left\| \cdot \right\|_{2}^{2} = \left( {\left\| \cdot \right\|_{2} } \right)^{2} = \mathop \sum \limits_{{t = \left[ {1, \ldots ,T} \right]}} \left| \cdot \right|^{2}\) being the squared \(\ell_{2}\)-norm.

  18. For the sake of clarification, we use for vector of 1 with dimensions \(\left( {N \times 1} \right)\) with \(N\) the number of the assets: \({\mathbf{1}}: = {\mathbf{1}}_{{\left( {N \times 1} \right)}}\) as a notation directly, whilst for a vector of 1 with dimensions \(\left( {T \times 1} \right)\), with \(T\) the number of dates of the time-series of returns on an asset, we denote it as: \({\mathbf{1}}_{{\left( {T \times 1} \right)}}\). Furthermore, we use the notations: \({\mathbf{1}}_{{\left( {T \times 1} \right)}}\) for a \(\left( {T \times 1} \right)\) vector of 1 when observations (dates) are at stake (instead of \({\mathbf{1}}\) as used by Britten-Jones, 1999, p. 658).

  19. Or, alternatively, by Stevens (1998) or Kempf and Memmel (2006) methods with same results.

  20. See Online Appendix for more details on the OLS approach.

  21. See Online Appendix on the Kempf and Memmel (2006) approach in the specific case of the GMVP.

  22. The \(\ell_{2}\)-norm penalization term is used in the Regularization of Inverse Discrete Gradient Estimator (RIDGE), such as (see Hoerl and Kennard, 1970, p. 56): \(P\left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right) = \left\| {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right\|_{2}^{2} = \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{N} \left| {{\text{w}}_{i} } \right|^{2}\) uses the squared \(\ell_{2}\)-norm, and both the \(\ell_{1}\)-norm and the squared \(\ell_{2}\)-norm are used in Elastic Net regularization such as (see Zou and Hastie, 2005, p. 304): \(P\left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right) = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left\| {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right\|_{2}^{2} + \alpha \left\| {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right\|_{1}\) where \(\alpha \in \left[ {0,1} \right]\). See Hastie et al., (2015, pp. 22 and 57) and also Kremer et al., (2020, p. 8) for geometric illustrations of the effects of such norms on coefficients.

  23. With \(\left\| \cdot \right\|_{q}^{k}\) denoting the power k of the \(\ell_{q}\)-norm operator, such as: \(\left\| {x_{i} } \right\|_{q}^{k} = \left( {\left\| {x_{i} } \right\|_{q} } \right)^{k} = \left( {\mathop \sum \limits_{{i \in {\mathbb{N}}}} \left| {x_{i} } \right|^{q} } \right)^{k/q}\). As mentioned before, we use in this equation the squared \(\ell_{2}\)-norm as: \(\left\| {{\mathbf{1}}\overline{\mu } - {\mathbf{Xw}}_{p} } \right\|_{2}^{2} = \left\| {\varvec{u}} \right\|_{2}^{2} = \left( {\mathop \sum \limits_{{t = \left[ {1, \ldots ,T} \right]}} \left| {u_{t} } \right|^{2} } \right)\), where \(u_{t}\) is the tth element of the vector of residuals denoted \({\varvec{u}} = \left( {{\mathbf{1}}\overline{\mu } - {\mathbf{Xw}}_{p} } \right)\)—see Eq. (22) for instance.

  24. As mentioned previously, the \(\ell_{1}\)-norm penalization term in LASSO regression writes in Eq. (22) as \(P\left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right) = \left\| {{\mathbf{w}}_{p} } \right\|_{1} = \mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} \left| {w_{i} } \right|\) as in Brodie et al. (2009), p. 12,268.

  25. In order to avoid concentrated and time-varying portfolios, or to deal with liquidity problem as in Vieira and Filomena (2020—see Sect. 2.2.2, p. 1060), or limit transaction costs (e.g., Lobo et al., 2007) or impose cardinality constraints (e.g., Anagnostopoulos & Mamanis, 2011; Chang et al., 2000; Woodside-Oriakhi et al., 2011).

  26. Equals here to 4000 in our restricted Chinese illustration sample.

  27. Equals here to 7800 in our illustrative sample.

  28. This relies on the expected return of the risk-free asset, where we find that the distance between Portfolio (\(N\)) and (\(T\)) in the Chinese and US market (with a higher return on the risk-free asset) is significantly higher than that in the French market (with a very low expected return of the risk-free asset).

  29. Whilst the same result does not hold in all markets: the Capitalized-Weighted Index in the French market is not optimal for instance.

  30. For instance, the computation of the whole Efficient Frontier on the high-dimensional data in the Chinese stock market with the Positively Constrained LASSO technique takes approximately 35 h on a 64 cores machine, whilst it takes less than a minute with a one core-computer when using the extended 4 fund TFST (with a related efficiency ratio of approximately 130,000).

References

  • Abadie, J. (1969). Generalization of the Wolfe reduced gradient method to the case of nonlinear constraints. Optimization, 22, 37–47.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Anagnostopoulos, K., & Mamanis, G. (2011). The mean-variance cardinality constrained portfolio optimization problem: An experimental evaluation of five multi-objective evolutionary algorithms. Expert Systems with Applications, 38(11), 14208–14217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, D. (1991). Heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimation. Econometrica, 59, 817–858.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, D., & Monahan, J. (1992). An improved heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimator. Econometrica, 60, 953–966.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Bai, L., Newsom, P., & Zhang, J. (2011). Teaching utility theory with an application in modern portfolio optimization. Decision Sciences Journal of Innovative Education, 9(1), 107–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belloni, A., & Chernozhukov, V. (2011). penalized quantile regression in high-dimensional sparse models. The Annals of Statistics, 39(1), 82–130.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, C., De Vecchi, C., & Vanduffel, S. (2021). When do two-or three-fund separation theorems hold? Quantitative Finance, 21, 1–15.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Black, F. (1972). Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. The Journal of Business, 45(3), 444–455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, F., & Litterman, R. (1992). Global portfolio optimization. Financial Analysts Journal, 48(5), 28–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccolto G., Caporin, M., & Maillet, B. (2021). Large financial network via conditional expected shortfall. Mimeo. R&R in the European Journal of Operational Research.

  • Bonaccolto, G., Caporin, M., & Paterlini, S. (2018). Asset allocation strategies based on penalized quantile regression. Computational Management Science, 15(1), 1–32.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccolto, G., & Paterlini, S. (2020). Developing new portfolio strategies by aggregation. Annals of Operations Research, 292(2), 933–971.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Breuer, T., & Csiszár, I. (2013). Systematic stress tests with entropic plausibility constraints. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(5), 1552–1559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuer, T., Jandacka, M., Rheinberger, K., & Summer, M. (2009). How to find plausible, severe, and useful stress scenarios. International Journal of Central Banking, 5, 205–224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Britten-Jones, M. (1999). The sampling error in estimates of mean-variance efficient portfolio weights. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 655–671.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broadie, M. (1993). Computing efficient frontiers using estimated parameters. Annals of Operations Research, 45(1), 21–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brodie, J., Daubechies, I., De Mol, C., Giannone, D., & Loris, I. (2009). Sparse and stable Markowitz portfolios. Proceedings of the National Academic Science of the USA, 106(30), 12267–12272.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Cairns, A. J., Blake, D., & Dowd, K. (2006). Stochastic lifestyling: Optimal dynamic asset allocation for defined contribution pension plans. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(5), 843–877.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Candelon, B., Hurlin, C., & Tokpavi, S. (2012). Sampling error and double shrinkage estimation of minimum variance portfolios. Journal of Empirical Finance, 19(4), 511–527.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cass, D., & Stiglitz, J. (1970). The structure of investor preferences and asset returns, and separability in portfolio allocation: A contribution to the pure theory of mutual funds. Journal of Economic Theory, 2(2), 122–160.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, T., Meade, N., Beasley, J., & Sharaiha, Y. (2000). Heuristics for cardinality constrained portfolio optimisation. Computers & Operations Research, 27(13), 1271–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlquist, M., Farago, A., & Tédongap, R. (2017). Asymmetries and portfolio choice. The Review of Financial Studies, 30(2), 667–702.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deguest, R., Martellini, L., & Milhau, V. (2018). A reinterpretation of the optimal demand for risky assets in fund separation theorems. Management Science, 64(9), 4333–4347.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Meo, E. (2021). Scenario design for macro-financial stress testing. SSRN 3493554.

  • DeMiguel, V., Garlappi, L., Nogales, F., & Uppal, R. (2009a). A generalized approach to portfolio optimization: Improving performance by constraining portfolio norms. Management Science, 55(5), 798–812.

    Google Scholar 

  • DeMiguel, V., Garlappi, L., & Uppal, R. (2009b). Optimal versus naive diversification: How inefficient is the 1/N portfolio strategy? The Review of Financial Studies, 22(5), 1915–1953.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duchin, R., & Levy, H. (2009). Markowitz versus the Talmudic portfolio diversification strategies. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 35(2), 71–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dybvig, P., & Liu, F. (2018). On investor preferences and mutual fund separation. Journal of Economic Theory, 174, 224–260.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, J., Zhang, J., & Yu, K. (2012). Vast portfolio selection with gross-exposure constraints. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 107(498), 592–606.

    MathSciNet  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Fastrich, B., Paterlini, S., & Winker, P. (2015). Constructing optimal sparse portfolios using regularization methods. Computational Management Science, 12(3), 417–434.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Flood, M., & Korenko, G. (2015). Systematic scenario selection: Stress testing and the nature of uncertainty. Quantitative Finance, 15(1), 43–59.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Gaines, B., Kim, J., & Zhou, H. (2018). Algorithms for fitting the constrained lasso. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 27(4), 861–871.

    MathSciNet  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Geyer, A., Hanke, M., & Weissensteiner, A. (2014). No-arbitrage bounds for financial scenarios. European Journal of Operational Research, 236(2), 657–663.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Gouriéroux, C., & Jouneau, F. (1999). Econometrics of efficient fitted portfolios. Journal of Empirical Finance, 6(1), 87–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grover, J., & Lavin, A. (2007). Modern portfolio optimization: A practical approach using an excel solver single-index model. The Journal of Wealth Management, 10(1), 60–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakansson, N. H. (1969). Risk disposition and the separation property in portfolio selection. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 4, 401–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hastie, T., Tibshirani, R., & Wainwright, M. (2015). Statistical learning with sparsity: The lasso and generalizations. CRC Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, C., & Siddique, A. (2000). Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests. The Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1263–1295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoerl, A., & Kennard, R. (1970). Ridge regression: Biased estimation for nonorthogonal problems. Technometrics, 12(1), 55–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, C., & Litzenberger, R. (1988). Foundations for financial economics. North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingersoll, J. (1987). Theory of financial decision making. Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Israelsen, C. (2003). Sharpening the Sharpe ratio. Financial Planning, 33(1), 49–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Israelsen, C. (2005). A refinement to the Sharpe ratio and information ratio. Journal of Asset Management, 5(6), 423–427.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan, R., & Ma, T. (2003). Risk reduction in large portfolios: Why imposing the wrong constraints helps. The Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1651–1683.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jobson, J., & Korkie, B. (1981). Performance hypothesis testing with the Sharpe and Treynor measures. Journal of Finance, 36, 889–908.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joo, Y., & Park, S. (2021). Optimal portfolio selection using a simple double-shrinkage selection rule. Finance Research Letters, 43, 102019.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorion, P. (1986). Bayes-Stein estimation for portfolio analysis. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 21, 279–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jurczenko, E., & Maillet, B. (2006). The four-moment capital asset pricing model: between asset pricing and asset allocation. In Multi-moment asset allocation and pricing models, Chapter 6 (pp. 113-163). Wiley.

  • Kan, R., & Zhou, G. (2007). Optimal portfolio choice with parameter uncertainty. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42, 621–656.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kempf, A., & Memmel, C. (2006). Estimating the global minimum variance portfolio. Schmalenbach Business Review, 58(4), 332–348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolm, P., Tütüncü, R., & Fabozzi, F. (2014). 60 Years of portfolio optimization: Practical challenges and current trends. European Journal of Operational Research, 234(2), 356–371.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Kremer, P., Lee, S., Bogdan, M., & Paterlini, S. (2020). Sparse portfolio selection via the sorted -norm. Journal of Banking and Finance, 110, 105687.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laws, J. (2003). Portfolio analysis using excel. Applied quantitative methods for trading and investment, 293.

  • Ledoit, O., & Wolf, M. (2008). Robust performance hypothesis testing with the Sharpe ratio. Journal of Empirical Finance, 15(5), 850–859.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledoit, O., & Wolf, M. (2011). Robust performances hypothesis testing with the variance. Wilmott, 2011(55), 86–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lintner, J. (1965a). The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(1), 13–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lintner, J. (1965b). Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. The Journal of Finance, 20(4), 587–615.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. W. (2002). The statistics of Sharpe ratios. Financial Analysts Journal, 58(4), 36–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lobo, M., Fazel, M., & Boyd, S. (2007). Portfolio optimization with linear and fixed transaction costs. Annals of Operations Research, 152(1), 341–365.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • MacKinlay, A., & Pástor, Ľ. (2000). Asset pricing models: Implications for expected returns and portfolio selection. The Review of Financial Studies, 13(4), 883–916.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahalanobis, P. (1927). Analysis of race-mixture in Bengal. Journal of the Asiatic Society of Bengal, 23, 301–333.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahalanobis, P. (1936). On the generalized distance in statistics. National Institute of Science of India.

  • Mardia, K., Kent, J., & Bibby, J. (1979). Multivariate analysis. Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. (1959). Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments. Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. M. (1999). The early history of portfolio theory: 1600–1960. Financial Analysts Journal, 55(4), 5–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. (2014). Mean-variance approximations to expected utility. European Journal of Operational Research, 234(2), 346–355.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • McNeil, A., Frey, R., & Embrechts, P. (2015). Quantitative risk management: Concepts, techniques and tools. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Memmel, C. (2003). Performance hypothesis testing with the Sharpe ratio. Finance Research Letters, 1, 21–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. (1973). An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica, 41(5), 867–887.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Meucci, A. (2009). Risk and asset allocation. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaud, R. (1989). The Markowitz optimization enigma: Is ‘optimized’ optimal? Financial Analysts Journal, 45(1), 31–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaud, R., & Michaud, R. (2008). Estimation error and portfolio optimization: A resampling solution. Journal of Investment Management, 6(1), 8–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica, 34, 768–783.

    Google Scholar 

  • Opdyke, J. (2007). Comparing Sharpe ratios: So where are the p-values? Journal of Asset Management, 8(5), 308–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pye, G. (1967). Portfolio selection and security prices. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 49(1), 111–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. (1977). A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests. Journal of Financial Economics, 4, 129–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. (1978). Mutual fund separation in financial theory—The separating distributions. Journal of Economic Theory, 17(2), 254–286.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1967). General proof that diversification pays. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 2(1), 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schanbacher, P. (2015). Averaging across asset allocation models. Jahrbücher Für Nationalökonomie Und Statistik, 235(1), 61–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, W. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425–442.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, G. (1998). On the inverse of the covariance matrix in portfolio analysis. The Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1821–1827.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. (1958). Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. The Review of Economic Studies, 25(2), 65–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tibshirani, R. (1996). Regression shrinkage and selection via the lasso. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B (methodological), 58(1), 267–288.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Tu, J., & Zhou, G. (2011). Markowitz meets Talmud: A combination of sophisticated and naive diversification strategies. Journal of Financial Economics, 99(1), 204–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turlach, B., & Wright, S. (2015). Quadratic programming. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Computational Statistics, 7(2), 153–159.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Vieira, E., & Filomena, T. (2020). Liquidity constraints for portfolio selection based on financial volume. Computational Economics, 56, 1055–1077.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vinod, H., & Morey, M. (1999). Confidence intervals and hypothesis testing for the Sharpe and Treynor performance measures: A bootstrap approach. Computational Finance, 99, 25–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodside-Oriakhi, M., Lucas, C., & Beasley, J. (2011). Heuristic algorithms for the cardinality constrained efficient frontier. European Journal of Operational Research, 213(3), 538–550.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, Y. (2000). Combining different procedures for adaptive regression. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 74(1), 135–161.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, Y. (2001). Adaptive regression by mixing. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 96(454), 574–588.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, Y. (2004). Aggregating regression procedures to improve performance. Bernoulli, 10(1), 25–47.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Yen, Y., & Yen, T. (2014). Solving norm constrained portfolio optimization via coordinate-wise descent algorithms. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 76, 737–759.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, Z., Ledoit, O., & Jiang, H. (2020). Risk reduction and efficiency increase in large portfolios: leverage and shrinkage. University of Zurich, Department of Economics, Working Paper, No. 328, 34 p.

  • Zou, H., & Hastie, T. (2005). Regularization and variable selection via the elastic net. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B (statistical Methodology), 67(2), 301–320.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Philippe Bernard, François Quittard-Pinon for previous collaborations on this topic, as well as Jean-Charles Garibal for preliminary research assistance, and Jean-Luc Prigent and Thierry Roncalli for their positive suggestions when writing first drafts of this article. We also sincerely appreciate the constructive discussion by Dionisis Philippas during the FEM2021 conference (Paris, June 2021). We are also grateful to the participants of the XXXVth AFFI Conference, of the XXXVth JMA conference, as well as Referees of the IFC2020, the ISFBI2021 and the FEM2021 conferences, as well as the Editor of ANOR in charge and the two anonymous Referees for their fair comments and suggestions. Resources linked to this article are available on: www.performance-metrics.eu. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiang Zhang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Costola, M., Maillet, B., Yuan, Z. et al. Mean–variance efficient large portfolios: a simple machine learning heuristic technique based on the two-fund separation theorem. Ann Oper Res 334, 133–155 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04881-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04881-3

Keywords

Navigation