Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Innovation benefits from nuclear phase-out: can they compensate the costs?

  • Published:
Climatic Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates whether an inefficient allocation of abatement due to constraints on the use of currently available low carbon mitigation options can promote innovation in new technologies and have a positive impact on welfare. We focus on the case of a nuclear power phase-out and endogenous technical change in energy efficiency and alternative low carbon technologies. The research is inspired by the re-thinking about nuclear power deployment which took place in some countries, especially in Western Europe, after the Fukushima accident in March 2011. The analysis uses an Integrated Assessment Model, WITCH, which features multiple externalities related to greenhouse gas emissions and innovation market failures. Our results show that phasing out nuclear power stimulates R&D investments and deployment of technologies with large learning potential. The resulting technology benefits that would not otherwise occur due to intertemporal and international externalities almost completely offset the economic costs of foregoing nuclear power. The extent of technology benefits depends on the stringency of the climate policy and is distributed unevenly across countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the notation of the equations, the second subscript indicates the variable with respect to which the cost function is differentiated, \( {c}_{2a}=\frac{\partial {C}_2}{\partial a},{c}_{2z}=\frac{\partial {C}_2}{\partial Z},{C}_{2H}=\frac{\partial {C}_2}{\partial H}. \)

  2. The referendum had been planned long before the Japanese accident, and was scheduled for June 2011, which turned out to be only 3 months after the accident.

  3. For additional information on single countries’ strategies (net of Japan’s predicted policy change), see for instance Rogner (2013).

  4. See IAEA and WNA statistics.

  5. It is not within the scopes of this paper, instead, to deeply investigate what could be the technology solutions to replace nuclear. It suffices to say that there is an on-going debate on this issue, see among others, Steinke et al. (2013), Delucchi and Jacobson (2011a, b), Trainer (2012), and Tavoni and van der Zwaan (2009).

  6. Incidentally, large-scale fission nuclear power may well be considered a mature technology, having been deployed starting from the 50s and definitively consolidated during the 70s and 80s. As such, it is characterized by low learning rates and potentials, and specifically lower than the other low-carbon technologies with which it would compete (Kahouli-Brahmi 2008).

  7. See www.witchmodel.org for model description and related papers.

  8. Concerning the offshore investment cost, the reported value is an average for the different offshore categories, where costs vary as a function of sea depth and distance from shore of the installation. The breakthrough investment cost is naturally somewhat arbitrary, fixed roughly ten times higher than traditional technologies’ average one.

  9. The expression “technology benefits” refers to the innovation benefits related to R&D and to the technological benefits associated with the deployment of infant technologies characterized by LbD related to experience.

  10. Policy costs measured in terms of GDP are larger, but we focus on consumption as a better indicator of welfare. In the 450 ppme scenario, the GDP loss without nuclear power would be 3.71 % and it would increase to 4.47 %, should technology benefits be excluded.

  11. For example, in the 450 ppme case reported in Figure 3 relative technology benefits would be equal to 0.39/(3.17–2.74) = 91 %.

References

  • Arrow KJ (1962) The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud 29(3):155–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Badcock J, Lenzen M (2010) Subsidies for electricity-generating technologies: a review. Energy Policy 38(2010):5038–5047

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, Carraro C, Galeotti M, Massetti E, Tavoni M (2006) WITCH: a world induced technical change hybrid model. Energy J :13–38. doi:10.2139/ssrn.948382

  • Bosetti V, De Cian E, Sgobbi A, Tavoni M (2009) The 2008 WITCH model: new model features and baseline. Working Papers 2009.85, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei

  • Bramoullé Y, Olson LJ (2005) Allocation of pollution abatement under learning by doing. J Publ Econ 89(9):1935–1960

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Cian E, Tavoni M (2012) Do technology externalities justify restrictions on emission permit trading? Resour Energy Econ 34(2012):624–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Cian E, Bosetti V, Tavoni M (2012) Technology innovation and diffusion in less than ideal climate policies. An assessment with the WITCH model. Clim Change 114(1):121–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delucchi MA, Jacobson MZ (2011a) Providing all global energy with wind, water, and solar power, part I: technologies, energy resources, quantities and areas of infrastructure, and materials. Energy Policy 39(2011):1154–1169

    Google Scholar 

  • Delucchi MA, Jacobson MZ (2011b) Providing all global energy with wind, water, and solar power, part II: reliability, system and transmission costs, and policies. Energy Policy 39(2011):1170–1190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerlagh R, Kverndokk S, Rosendahl K (2009) Optimal timing of climate change policy: interaction between carbon taxes and innovation externalities. Environ Resour Econ 43(3):369–390

    Google Scholar 

  • Golombek R, Hoel M (2006) Second-best climate agreements and technology policy. Adv Econ Anal Policy 6(1). Available at: http://works.bepress.com/rolf_golombek/1

  • Goulder LH, Mathai K (2000) Optimal CO2 abatement in the presence of induced technological change. J Environ Econ Manag 39:1–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder LH, Schneider SH (1999) Induced technological change and the attractiveness of CO2 abatement policies. Resour Energy Econ 21(3–4):211–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoogwijk M, van Vuuren D, de Vries B, Turkenburg W (2007) Exploring the impact on cost and electricity production of high penetration levels of intermittent electricity in OECD Europe and the USA, results for wind energy. Energy 32(2007):1381–1402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahouli-Brahmi S (2008) Technological learning in energy–environment–economy modelling: a survey. Energy Policy 36(2008):138–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kriegler E, Weyant J, Blanford G, Clarke L, Tavoni M, Krey V, Riahi K, Fawcett A, Richels R, Edmonds J (2013) Overview of the EMF 27 study on energy system transition pathways under alternative climate policy regimes. Climatic Change, this issue

  • Lipsey RG, Lancaster L (1956) The general theory of second best. Rev Econ Stud 24(1):11–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otto VM, Löschel A, Reilly J (2008) Directed technical change and differentiation of climate policy. Energy Econ 30(2008):2855–2878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogner HH (2013) World outlook for nuclear power. Energy Strateg Rev 1(2013):291–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Politic Econ 94:1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosendahl KE (2004) Cost-effective environmental policy: implications of induced technological change. J Environ Econ Manag 48(3):1099–1121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinke F, Wolfrum P, Hoffmann C (2013) Grid vs. Storage in a 100% renewable Europe. Renew Energy 50(2013):826–832

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan P, Krey V, Riahi K (2013) Impacts of considering electric sector variability and reliability in the MESSAGE model. Energy Strateg Rev 1(2013):157–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavoni M, van der Zwaan B (2009) Nuclear versus Coal plus CCS: a comparison of two competitive base-load climate control options, Working Papers 2009.100, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei

  • Tavoni M, De Cian E, Luderer G, Steckel J, Waisman H (2012) The value of technology and of its evolution towards a low carbon economy. Clim Change 114(1):39–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trainer T (2012) A critique of Jacobson and Delucchi’s proposals for a world renewable energy supply. Energy Policy 44:476–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Enrica De Cian.

Additional information

The research leading to these results has received funding from the Italian Ministry of Education, University and Research and the Italian Ministry of Environment, Land and Sea under the GEMINA project.

This article is part of the Special Issue on “The EMF27 Study on Global Technology and Climate Policy Strategies” edited by John Weyant, Elmar Kriegler, Geoffrey Blanford, Volker Krey, Jae Edmonds, Keywan Riahi, Richard Richels, and Massimo Tavoni.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(DOCX 535 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

De Cian, E., Carrara, S. & Tavoni, M. Innovation benefits from nuclear phase-out: can they compensate the costs?. Climatic Change 123, 637–650 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-013-0870-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-013-0870-9

Keywords

Navigation