Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Coups d’état and defense spending: a counterfactual analysis

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We explore how institutional set-ups, in particular changes in political institutions through coups d’état, can affect the way military expenditures are determined. We use a counterfactual approach, the synthetic control method, and compare the evolution of the military burden for 40 countries affected by coups with the evolution of a synthetic counterfactual that replicates the initial conditions and the potential outcomes of the countries of interest before exposure to coups. Our case studies suggest that successful coups result in a large increase in the military burden. However, when no effects or a decrease in the defense burden are found, it is often the consequence of a democratization process triggered by the coup. These results are in keeping with recent theoretical developments on the bargaining power of the military in authoritarian regimes. Failed coups, by contrast, produce a smaller, and mostly positive, effect on the military burden, possibly as a result of the incumbent’s strategy to avert further challenges to the stability of the regime by buying off the military.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, e.g. Landau (1993), Dunne et al. (2005), Aizenman and Glick (2006), Pieroni (2009), Dunne and Smith (2010), Alptekin and Levine (2011) and Kollias and Paleologou (2013).

  2. The military burden in times of peace varies from zero (e.g. Costa Rica) to less than 0.2 % (e.g. Haiti, Panama or Iceland) to more than 14 % of the GDP (e.g. Saudi Arabia). In times of war the military burden can exceed a nation’s entire GDP (e.g. Kuwait).

  3. Acemoglu et al’s study joins traditional theories of the incentives and constraints faced by all dictators who wish to remain in power (see, e.g. Kurrild-Klitgaard 2000; Crespo Cuaresma et al. 2011; Wintrobe 2012). Tullock (2005) offers a seminal and masterful scientific analysis of dictatorships and individual behaviour under autocracy by means of a rational choice model.

  4. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this caveat.

  5. Imbens and Wooldridge (2009) survey the literature on program evaluation and provide the potential outcomes formulation, while Pesaran and Smith (2012) discuss ex ante and ex post counterfactual analyses in the case of macroeconometric applications.

  6. In those cases, the weight is often negligible (e.g. in constructing Pakistan’s counterfactual, the algorithm assigned a weight of 0.001 to India).

  7. Note that existing connections between countries, such as ethnic or political ties, may also cause military spending in one country to be affected by a coup in a non-neighboring country. Yet, links between countries may be multiple and often difficult to measure.

  8. See Leon (2014) for a survey of the literature on the economic causes of coups.

  9. http://www.systemicpeace.org.

  10. http://www.prio.no/Data/Armed-Conflict/UCDP-PRIO/.

  11. According to our dataset, the average duration of a military regime is less than eight years. Marinov and Goemans (2013) combine two datasets to cover 249 distinct coup spells in 164 countries between 1945 and 2004 and find that the average duration of a spell is around eight years. Seven years is a safer choice for two reasons: first, the accuracy of this method in predicting the counterfactual level of military burden declines as we move away from the coup year; second, the longer the duration of a spell, the more likely a new regime change will occur. The military burden may then be affected by expectations of a soon-to-come regime change.

  12. The root mean square predicted error (RMSPE) measures the pre-treatment fit between the path of the outcome variable for any particular country and its synthetic counterpart. The lower is the RMSPE the better is the fit.

  13. We make an exception to this rule and consider the attempted coup in Venezuela in 2002, as we deem it an informative case.

  14. Given the limits on the length of the article, we do not include the tables for the remaining cases, but make them available in the online appendix on the authors’ webpages (www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/pais/people/bove/ and https://sites.google.com/site/rnistico/home).

  15. To avoid cluttering the figures, we do not show experiments with a pre-treatment Root Mean Squared Prediction Error (RMSPE) twice that of the treated country.

  16. See http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/pais/people/bove/ and https://sites.google.com/site/rnistico/home.

  17. To submit our results to a further robustness check, we have also run a panel data analysis, in particular a number of difference-in-difference estimations, and use three different types of treatments: successful coups, failed coups, and regime changes unrelated to coups. We look at the seven-year window following the coup. Results show that, on average, successful coups tend to increase the military burden, while both failed coups or other types of regime changes do not have any significant effect. This is consistent with most of our findings. Due to space limitations these data are not presented here, but are shown in the Online Appendix.

References

  • Abadie, A., Diamond, A., & Hainmueller, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of california’s tobacco control program. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105(490), 493–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abadie, A., & Gardeazabal, J. (2003). The economic costs of conflict: A case study of the basque country. The American Economic Review, 93(1), 113–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Ticchi, D., & Vindigni, A. (2010). A theory of military dictatorships. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(1), 1–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman, J., & Glick, R. (2006). Military expenditure, threats, and growth. Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 15(2), 129–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albalate, D., Bel, G., & Elias, F. (2012). Institutional determinants of military spending. Journal of Comparative Economics, 40(2), 279–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alptekin, A., & Levine, P. (2011). Military expenditure and economic growth: A meta-analysis. European Journal of Political Economy, 28(4), 636–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Robinson, J. A. (2010). Quis custodiet ipsos custodes? Civilian control over the military. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(2–3), 655–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bove, V., & Nisticò, R. (2014). Military in politics and budgetary allocations. Journal of Comparative Economics. doi:10.1016/j.jce.2014.02.002.

  • Bratton, M., & Van de Walle, N. (1994). Neopatrimonial regimes and political transitions in Africa. World Politics, 46(04), 453–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brauner, J. L. N. (2012). Military spending and democratization. Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 18(3), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotet, A. M., & Tsui, K. K. (2013). Oil and conflict: What does the cross country evidence really show? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(1), 49–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespo Cuaresma, J., Oberhofer, H., & Raschky, P. A. (2011). Oil and the duration of dictatorships. Public Choice, 148(3–4), 505–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1997). Common agency and coordination: General theory and application to government policy making. Journal of Political Economy, 105(4), 752–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P., & Perlo-Freeman, S. (2003). The demand for military spending in developing countries: A dynamic panel analysis. Defence and Peace Economics, 14(6), 461–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P., Perlo-Freeman, S., & Smith, R. P. (2008). The demand for military expenditure in developing countries: Hostility versus capability. Defence and Peace Economics, 19(4), 293–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P., & Smith, R. P. (2010). Military expenditure and granger causality: A critical review. Defence and Peace Economics, 21(5–6), 427–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P., Smith, R. P., & Willenbockel, D. (2005). Models of military expenditure and growth: A critical review. Defence and Peace Economics, 16(6), 449–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geddes, B., Wright, J., & Frantz, E. (2012). Authoritarian regimes: A new data set. http://dictators.la.psu.edu/pdf/gwf-code-book-1.1.

  • Goldsmith, B. E. (2003). Bearing the defense burden, 1886–1989 why spend more? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(5), 551–573.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hewitt, D. (1992). Military expenditures worldwide: Determinants and trends, 1972–1988. Journal of Public Policy, 12, 105–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huntington, S. P. (1995). Reforming civil–military relations. Journal of Democracy, 6(4), 9–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G., & Wooldridge, J. (2009). Recent developments in the econometrics of program evaluation. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(1), 5–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollias, C., & Paleologou, S.-M. (2013). Guns, highways and economic growth in the United States. Economic Modelling, 30, 449–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2000). The constitutional economics of autocratic succession. Public Choice, 103(1–2), 63–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landau, D. L. (1993). The economic impact of military expenditures (Vol. 1138). Oklahoma: World Bank Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leon, G. (2014). Loyalty for sale? Military spending and coups detat. Public Choice, 8, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Looney, R. E., & Frederiksen, P. C. (1990). The economic determinants of military expenditure in selected east asian countries. Contemporary Southeast Asia, 11(4), 265–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maizels, A., & Nissanke, M. K. (1986). The determinants of military expenditures in developing countries. World Development, 14(9), 1125–1140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marinov, N., & Goemans, H. (2013). Coups and democracy. British Journal of Political Science, 42, 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mbaku, J. M. (1991). Military expenditures and bureaucratic competition for rents. Public Choice, 71(1–2), 19–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nannicini, T., & Ricciuti, R. (2010). Autocratic transitions and growth. CESifo working paper.

  • Nordhaus, W., Oneal, J. R., & Russett, B. (2012). The effects of the international security environment on national military expenditures: A multicountry study. International Organization, 66(03), 491–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordlinger, E. (1977). Soldiers in politics: Military coups and governments. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M.H., & Smith, R. (2012). Counterfactual analysis in macroeconometrics: An empirical investigation into the effects of quantitative easing. IZA Discussion Paper, p. 6618

  • Pieroni, L. (2009). Military expenditure and economic growth. Defence and Peace Economics, 20(4), 327–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, J. (2012). Determinants of the attempting and outcome of coups d’etat. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56(6), 1017–1040.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, J. M., & Thyne, C. L. (2011). Global instances of coups from 1950 to 2010 a new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 48(2), 249–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(3), 51–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Russet, B., & Oneal, J. (2001). Triangulating peace. New York: WW Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. (1995). The demand for military expenditure. Handbook of Defense Economics, 1, 69–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. P. (2009). Military economics: The interaction of power and money. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005). The social dilemma: Of autocracy, revolution, coup d’état, and war. (Selected Works of Gordon Tullock, Vol. 8). volume 8. Liberty Fund Inc., Indianapolis.

  • Whitten, G. D., & Williams, L. K. (2011). Buttery guns and welfare hawks: The politics of defense spending in advanced industrial democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 55(1), 117–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (2012). Autocracy and coups d’etat. Public Choice, 152(1–2), 115–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Emanuele Ciani, Claudio Deiana, Leandro Elia, Ludovica Giua, Tommaso Oliviero, Matthias Parey, David Reinstein, Ron Smith, Alberto Tumino, Tiziana Venittelli and participants at the 2014 Annual Conference of the Royal Economic Society and at the 2014 Annual Meeting of the European Public Choice Society for their helpful comments. We also thank three anonymous referees for their constructive comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vincenzo Bove.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bove, V., Nisticò, R. Coups d’état and defense spending: a counterfactual analysis. Public Choice 161, 321–344 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0202-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0202-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation