Skip to main content
Log in

Risk Aversion and the Size of Desired Debt

  • Research paper
  • Published:
Italian Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate the determinants of the level of desired total, secured, and unsecured debt for a panel of Italian households over the period 1989–2016, accounting for both left censoring and sample selection. In particular, we focus on the role of households’ attitudes towards risks, using both their observed behaviour in the financial market and the responses to a hypothetical lottery choice question. We find risk aversion to be a significant determinant of the desired amount of unsecured, secured, and total debt. Relatively more risk adverse households desire more debt, suggesting that Italian households may rely on debt to insure themselves against shocks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The optimal consumption path is a function of the coefficient of risk aversion when, for example, preferences are represented by the popular isoelastic utility function or the Epstein–Zin–Weil recursive utility.

  2. Attitudes toward risk represent a relevant factor in several decision making processes, like those concerning financial investments and portfolio choice (Gomes and Michaelides 2005; Barasinska et al. 2012), health insurance (Anderson and Mellor 2008; Schmitz 2011; Gandelman and Hernández-Murillo 2013), migration (Jaeger et al. 2010), labour market (Ahn 2010; Dohmen et al. 2010; Dohmen and Falk 2011; Pollmann et al. 2020), education (Castillo et al. 2011; Caner and Okten 2010; De Paola and Gioia 2012; Checchi et al. 2013), and marriage (Schmidt 2008; Spivey 2010; De Paola and Gioia 2017).

  3. We prefer this to other panel data estimators robust to selection bias, such as Kyriazidou (1997) and Rochina-Barrachina (1999), because it does not require any known distribution of the errors in the equations of interest but allows them to be heteroskedastic and serially correlated. Although this estimator can be employed when some of the explanatory variables are endogenous, we do not exploit this advantage.

  4. Most financial institutions have an upper limit on age when deciding whether to grant a loan. Since 2005, the Italian National Institute for Social Security allows pensioners to access salary-backed loans, where the Institute is directly responsible for repayments that are never higher than one fifth of the pension. This has enlarged the Italian market for loans to senior people, but options for those aged 90 years old and higher are basically non-existent.

  5. The phrasing of the question in 2000 is as follows: “You are offered the opportunity of buying shares which, tomorrow, with equal probability, will be worth either 10 million or nothing. How much would you be prepared to pay to buy these shares?"

  6. This is based on the model of expected utility, which has been the standard approach in economics to capture risk-aversion consideration. See O’Donoghue and Somerville (2018) for a review of its pros and cons.

  7. Eisenhauer and Ventura (2003) underline that one has to choose between considering the positive outcome of the postulated gamble as a gross or a net value, i.e. before or after tax. We opt for the latter.

  8. Results are robust to limiting the sample to only risk averse individuals. Results are available on request.

  9. We present the results for OLS, CRE, and CRTE only, since the Mundlak effects are always jointly significant (the other results are available on request). We also report the results from the Semykina and Wooldridge’s (2010) estimator, but it should be noted that the liquidity constrained questions are not referred to any of the two forms of credit in particular.

  10. However, it is important to observe that net wealth may be affected by simultaneity bias: the amount borrowed in a year influences the current level of wealth. We checked the robustness of our results to two alternative specifications, the first where we substitute the current value with the lagged value of net wealth, and the second where we remove the regressor from the analysis. In both cases, the results for the remaining explanatory variables are not affected by the change.

  11. To increase the number of observations, when the answer is missing we do as follows: for each households, we assign a value of zero in all the waves preceding the first 0 observed (i.e. we assume that the household did not know the answer in the preceding waves if she did not know the answer in the current wave), and a value of 1 to all the waves following the last 1 answered (i.e. we assume that the household learned the correct answer after she first answered it correctly).

  12. The percentage of total households’ liabilities on GDP in Italy has always been lower than the European mean. However, between 1995 and 2012 this indicator has more than doubled and, after a slowdown due to the effects of the financial crisis, has been recently recording high growth rates again. See e.g. Eurostat data available at https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/nasa_10_f_bs/default/table?lang=en.18.

References

  • Ahn T (2010) Attitudes toward risk and self-employment of young workers. Labour Econ 17:434–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson LR, Mellor JM (2008) Predicting health behaviors with an experimental measure of risk preference. J Health Econ 27:1260–1274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1965) Aspects of the Theory of Risk-Bearing, Yrjö Jahnssonin Säätiö. (Reprinted in 1971 in Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing, Markham Publishing, Chicago, pp 90–109)

  • Artavanis N, Karra S (2020) Financial literacy and student debt. Eur J Financ 26:382–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barasinska N, Schäfer D, Stephan A (2012) Individual risk attitudes and the composition of financial portfolios: Evidence from German household portfolios. Q Rev Econ Financ 52:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker TA, Shabani R (2010) Outstanding debt and the household portfolio. Rev Financ Stud 23:2900–2934

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown S, Garino G, Taylor K (2013) Household debt and attitudes toward risk. Rev Income Wealth 59:283–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Crossley TF (2009) Shocks, stocks, and socks: smoothing consumption over a temporary income loss. J Eur Econ Assoc 7:1169–1192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Lusardi A (1996) Household saving: Micro theories and micro facts. J Econ Lit 34:1797–1855

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunello G (2002) Absolute risk aversion and the returns to education. Econ Educ Rev 21:635–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caner A, Okten C (2010) Risk and career choice: evidence from Turkey. Econ Educ Rev 29:1060–1075

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castillo M, Ferraro P, Jordan J, Petrie R (2011) The today and tomorrow of kids: time preferences and educational outcomes of children. J Public Econ 95:1377–1385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavalletti B, Lagazio C, Vandone D, Lagomarsino E (2020) Consumer debt and financial fragility: evidence from Italy. J Consum Policy 43:725–747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain G (1982) Multivariate regression models for panel data. J Econom 18:5–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Checchi D, Fiorio CV, Leonardi M (2013) Intergenerational persistence of educational attainment in Italy. Econ Lett 118:229–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D, Jappelli T (1993) The effect of borrowing constraints on consumer liabilities. J Money Credit Bank 25:197–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Paola M, Gioia F (2012) Risk aversion and field of study choice: the role of individual ability. Bull Econ Res 64:s193–s209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Paola M, Gioia F (2017) Does patience matter for marriage stability? Some evidence from Italy. Rev Econ Household 15:549–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • del Rio A, Young G (2006) The determinants of unsecured borrowing: evidence from the BHPS. Appl Financ Econ 16:1119–1144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen T, Falk A (2011) Performance pay and multidimensional sorting: productivity, preferences, and gender. Am Econ Rev 101:556–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U (2010) Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? Am Econ Rev 100:1238–1260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duca JV, Rosenthal SS (1991) An econometric analysis of borrowing constraints and household debt, research paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

  • Dynan KE, Kohn DL (2007) The rise in U.S. household indebtedness: causes and consequences. In: Kent C, Lawson J (eds) The structure and resilience of the financial system, pp 84–122

  • Eisenhauer J, Ventura L (2003) Survey measures of risk aversion and prudence. Appl Econ 35:1477–1484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gandelman N, Hernández-Murillo R (2013) What do happiness and health satisfaction data tell us about relative risk aversion? J Econ Psychol 39:301–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgarakos D, Haliassos M, Pasini G (2014) Household debt and social interactions. Rev Financ Stud 27:1404–1433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomes F, Michaelides A (2005) Optimal life-cycle asset allocation: understanding the empirical evidence. J Financ 60:869–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gropp R, Scholz JK, White M (1996) Personal bankruptcy and credit supply and demand. Q J Econ 112:217–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermansson C (2018) Can self-assessed financial risk measures explain and predict bank customers’ objective financial risk? J Econ Behav Organ 148:226–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurst E, Stafford F (2004) Home is where the equity is: mortgage refinancing and household consumption. J Money Credit Bank 36:985–1014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaeger DA, Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U, Bonin H (2010) Direct evidence on risk attitudes and migration. Rev Econ Stat 92:684–689

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keys BJ (2018) The credit market consequences of job displacement. Rev Econ Stat 100:405–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyriazidou E (1997) Estimation of a panel data sample selection model. Econometrica 65:1335–1364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leece D (2000) Choice of mortgage instrument, liquidity constraints and the demand for housing debt in the UK. Appl Econ 32:1121–1132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Tufano P (2015) Debt literacy, financial experiences, and overindebtedness. J Pension Econ Financ 14:332–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magri S (2007) Italian households’ debt: the participation to the debt market and the size of the loan. Empirical Econ 33:401–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundlak Y (1978) On the pooling of time series and cross section data. Econometrica 46:69–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagano M, Yeom D (2014) Another determinant of household leverage: evidence from Japan’s mortgage loan data. Int Rev Financ 14:105–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue T, Somerville J (2018) Modeling risk aversion in economics. J Econ Perspect 32:91–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni A, Frey R, Bruhin A, Dutilh G, Hertwig R, Rieskamp J (2017) The risk elicitation puzzle. Nat Human Behav 1:803–809

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pence KM (2006) The role of wealth transformations: an application to estimating the effect of tax incentives on saving. B.E J Econ Anal Policy 5:1–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollmann D, Dohmen T, Palm FC (2020) Robust estimation of wage dispersion with censored data: an application to occupational earnings risk and risk attitudes. Economist 168:519–540

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt JW (1964) Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32:122–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin M (2000) Risk aversion and expected-utility theory: a calibration theorem. Econometrica 68:1281–1292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochina-Barrachina ME (1999) A new estimator for panel data sample selection models. Ann Econ Stat 55:153–181

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt L (2008) Risk preferences and the timing of marriage and childbearing. Demography 45:439–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz H (2011) Direct evidence of risk aversion as a source of advantageous selection in health insurance. Econ Lett 113:180–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Semykina A, Wooldridge JM (2010) Estimating panel data models in the presence of endogeneity and selection. J Econom 157:375–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spivey C (2010) Desperation or desire? The role of risk aversion in marriage. Econ Inquiry 48:499–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan JX (2008) Borrowing during unemployment: unsecured debt as a safety net. J Hum Resour 43:383–412

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (1995) Selection corrections for panel data models under conditional mean independence assumptions. J Econom 68:115–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandro Spiganti.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9 and 10.

Table 3 Stepwise adjustment of samples and average number of waves
Table 4 Variables and definitions
Table 5 Summary statistics for the entire sample
Table 6 Summary statistics for constrained sample
Table 7 Summary statistics for unconstrained sample
Table 8 Summary statistics depending on portfolio choices
Table 9 Secured and unsecured Debt versus the Arrow–Pratt measure, AMEs
Table 10 Total Debt versus financial literacy, AMEs

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lagomarsino, E., Spiganti, A. Risk Aversion and the Size of Desired Debt. Ital Econ J 9, 369–396 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-021-00172-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-021-00172-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation