Main

The energy sector is in a state of rapid change. Several countries announced a variety of ‘green’ policies to recover from the 2020 COVID-19 downturn. Many of these policies could have a long lasting effect on the oil and gas industry3,4. The industry could enter into an era of declining demand, technology-led supply response, intense competition, investors’ scepticism, and increasing public and government pressure regarding impacts of the oil sector on the environment4.

Environmental impacts of oil are commonly measured using LCA methods. The life-cycle carbon footprint, or CI of oil-derived transportation fuels (for example, gasoline) includes the greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions resulting from the combustion of fuels themselves as well as emissions from production and refining of petroleum products. So-called upstream emissions from exploration, extraction and transportation of crude oil differ widely between oilfields (~20–300 kg of CO2 equivalent per barrel (kgCO2e bbl−1) of oil) due to diverse sub-surface geological properties of the deposit, physical and thermodynamic properties of the hydrocarbons, and production and resource management practices1. Similarly, ‘midstream’ emissions from refining vary widely (~10–60 kgCO2e bbl−1 oil) due to the quality of stream of processed crude and the refining technologies applied5. These emissions contribute to variability in the life-cycle CI of different crude oil supply chains.

The profitability of crude oil production somewhat mirrors the heterogeneity in GHG emissions. The cost-effectiveness of the upstream sector varies due to the properties of the crude extracted, the marginal production costs, the capacity of the producers to affect the global oil price, and the global oil demand elasticity. Thus, some fields are very profitable, while others barely break even.

Recent studies have separately analysed the heterogeneity in the GHG emissions1,5 and the economics of the oil market (Benini, G. et al., manuscript in preparation). However, the interaction between the two remains poorly understood. As a result, the characteristics of marginally economic oilfields are not systematically available. This interaction is important because it affects the magnitude of emissions mitigation potential as less profitable oil producers are displaced when demand declines. The demand drops can be due to socio-economic effects (for example, recessions or the ongoing COVID-19 pandemic), substitution effects (for example, more extensive use of alternative fuels/vehicles), and technological change within the transportation sector (for example, greater fuel efficiency).

In the past decade, development of ‘consequential’ LCA aimed to incorporate numerous economic factors into previously static engineering-based analysis2,6,7,8. These analyses attempt to model income and substitution effects of introducing alternatives, instead of simply assuming that a new product directly displaces an old product. To date, this consequential LCA paradigm has not reached crude oil LCA, and studies of alternatives to crude oil (for example, electric vehicles (EVs)) nearly always assume that an alternative simply displaces average crude oil. The merging of CI and profitability allow us to conduct the first consequential LCA study of the global oil supply (to the best of our knowledge).

The present work connects the upstream CI of 1,933 oilfields (~90% of 2015 global crude production) with their profitability. The CI of fields is calculated using a well-to-refinery estimation tool, which assesses the emissions due to the production of an additional barrel of crude from a particular oilfield. The profitability is calculated using a microeconomic model, which determines how much money a company is willing to pay to manage an additional barrel of crude located in a particular oilfield (see Methods). The integration of field-specific CI and profitability allows us to identify the emissions of fields close to the break-even point (extensive margin of the industry). In other words, we isolate the emissions of those fields where the management choice hangs in the balance between ‘how much should I produce?’ and ‘should I keep producing or cease business operations?’

Our results suggest that an environmental policy designed around non-market informed LCA results could ignore first-order effects. In addition, the structure of the global oil market systematically affects the life-cycle benefits from a decline in oil demand. These results could serve public (for example, the US Department of Energy National Energy Modeling System) and private energy system models to better assess the benefits of technological change within the transportation sector.

Results and discussion

Country-level

Figure 1 presents the global map of national volume-weighted average (VWA) marginal production costs (MC) in 2015. The numbers below the name of each country in the map are the corresponding upstream VWA CIs (in kgCO2e bbl−1). The global average MC estimate—shown by the horizontal dashed line in Fig. 1—is ~US$5.9 bbl−1 crude oil, with country-level MCs ranging from 2.8 (Iraq (IRQ)) to US$21.5 bbl−1 (Columbia (COL)). Fields with the lowest production costs are mainly conventional resources located in the Middle East and North Africa. There is a wide range of production emissions associated with these regions, with routine flaring as the major driver of high CI due to lack of investment/infrastructure for gas handling (see Supplementary Information section 3.3).

Fig. 1: Estimated global crude oil upstream marginal cost of production (2015).
figure 1

National volume weighted average (VWA) upstream marginal cost of production in US$ bbl−1 crude oil produced. Map shows national VWA upstream marginal CI below each country name (in kgCO2e bbl−1 crude oil delivered to refinery). The global VWA MC estimate is shown by the horizontal dashed line (~US$5.6 bbl−1). Reference year is 2015. Top 30 global producers are mapped (see Supplementary Data 1 for full list). Countries are named based on their ISO 3 code. Colour scheme reflects national VWA MC: dark blue for lowest MC, dark red for highest MC.

Among large producers, Venezuelan, Mexican and Canadian oils are the most expensive and tend to have high production CIs. The US oil industry stands near the global average in terms of GHG emissions and  has a high MC (~US$7.3 bbl−1).

Note that the dynamics of the emissions presented in Fig. 1 can vary over time9,10. However, due to the fact that substantial change in production strategies takes time, the relative magnitude of the presented emissions can be expected to hold for a short-term outlook of <5–10 years. See Supplementary Information section 3.1 for production economics time-series dissection.

Crude type

Table 1 groups field-level results into summary statistics of a set of global crude classes. Heavy fields (most commonly located in Venezuela) and extra heavy fields (mostly located in Canada) are the least profitable fields with relatively high MC and low selling price (due to low API gravity). Oil sands have the lowest selling oil price due to low API gravity and high sulfur content. However, their MCs have substantially decreased in recent years11,12 making them more competitive vis-à-vis heavy and extra heavy crudes. Contrary to all the other types of crude, oil sands are all located in a single country (Canada). Therefore, they are particularly sensitive to national-specific shocks and transport logistics issues. Shale and tight oil resources are somewhat more competitive, with relatively higher profit margins in all three economic cases, lower emissions, and lighter density crude (higher selling price and lower refining emissions). Conventional light and medium fields are the largest and cheapest to extract crude oil with high selling price, low MC and relatively low CI.

Table 1 2015 global oilfields characteristics based on crude type

The average profitability (shadow price (SP)) of different crude types changes accordingly to the assumption on the market structure. In perfect competition (PC), every field is an independent firm, which exerts no market power. In oligopolistic competition (oligopoly), a limited number of firms owns many fields. In cartel competition (cartel), a limited number of firms coordinate their production decisions via a syndicate (for example, the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC)—see Methods). In PC, the oilfield SP is the difference between the price at which it sells its output and the MC. The conventional light and medium fields are the most profitable producing units (see SP-PC in Table 1). In oligopoly, the volume of production of the firm, which owns the field, affects its SP. In cartel, the volume of production of OPEC affects the SP of the field’s member of the union. As a result, in oligopoly and cartel cases, shutting down or reducing production from individually profitable oilfields is rational, since the firm/cartel will sell less output but at a higher price. As a result, in oligopoly and in cartel cases many light and medium fields owned by large international or national oil companies shift to a least profitable position.

Irrespectively of the underlying market structure, heavy fields tend to remain the least profitable formation. Thus, these are the crudes most likely to be displaced by an oil demand reduction. Carbon taxation would also significantly affect their profitability due to their high production CI. Gas management (that is, routine flaring and methane venting and fugitives) is the major CI contributor for light and medium, and shale and tight oil crudes. The profitability of these fields is therefore exposed to gas management regulations (for example, production restriction as imposed in eastern Canada13).

Field-level

To estimate field-level CI (see Methods), we separate the GHG emissions due to the production of the next barrel from the emissions due to the exploration, and drilling and development. The former identifies the environmental footprint linked to the SP of discovered oil (that is, the one identified in the econometric analysis). The latter—exploration and development emissions—are smaller in most cases and are coupled to the SP of undiscovered oil (not included in this work). Next, the computed SPs of discovered oilfields are sorted from smallest to largest (that is, low to high profitability). As a result, we obtain a merit base curve, which links profitability to production CI for the three market structures (PC, oligopoly and cartel—see Methods).

Figure 2 combines the upstream cumulative VWA CIs (right axis) and the sorted SPs (left axis), against the percentage of total oil production covered in this work. Analogous to the upstream CI1, the presented wide range of SPs illustrates heterogeneity of production costs due to diverse operational, physical, chemical, and geological properties of different oilfields. Fields in the highest fifth percentile (~US$53 bbl−1) make over 17% more marginal profit per barrel than the median field (~US$46 bbl−1) for all economic cases.

Fig. 2: Upstream cumulative volume-weighted average CIs (right axis) and sorted SPs (left axis) of global oilfields for PC, oligopoly and cartel economic cases versus the percentage of total oil production in 2015.
figure 2

The oil demand elasticity of η = −0.35 is used for both oligopoly and cartel competition cases. See Supplementary Information section 3.2 (Suppplementary Figs. 10 and 11) for results variation based on different oil demand elasticities and further discussions.

Each local peak along the CI curve in Fig. 2 indicates an addition of a field with relatively high CI and production rate compared to the preceding covered fields. For example, the early sharp peaks by using the cartel model (black curve in Fig. 2) correspond to Venezuelan heavy fields. Large peaks in cumulative CIs at the beginning (0–20% of total production) imply that many less-economic fields with relatively low SPs also emit high GHG emissions (few exceptions are unprofitable depleted conventional fields with low SP and low emissions). These marginal oilfields are consequently more vulnerable to any future carbon taxation/regulation regime and more likely to be displaced by a demand shift.

In all economic cases, the cumulative CI curve trends downward due to covering fewer emitting fields. This trend continues for the PC case until reaching 51.9 kgCO2e bbl−1 (at 100% production coverage), which is the global VWA marginal CI (see Table 1). However, for the other two cases (that is, oligopoly and cartel), including the global oil demand elasticity and market power correction in computing the SP results in less profitability of several low-emitting conventional producers. Thus, for oligopoly and cartel models after few high peaks, the cumulative CI curve first trends descending (conventional with low CI) and later trends ascending (remaining fields with higher CI than conventional closer to margin). See Supplementary Information section 3.3 and Supplementary Data 1 for field-level additional data.

Displacement implications

Many reports estimate near and long-term volume of oil that is going to be displaced and/or stranded by technological developments and/or policy measures14,15,16,17,18. These estimates depend on numerous scenario assumptions (for example, growth rate of EVs, global income growth and the way these factors interact) and their conclusions differ markedly.

Instead of selecting any one scenario, we create abstract round number shocks to identify the environmental effect resulting from the displacement of the extensive margin of the oil industry. Such shocks might stem from policies to counter climate change, economic slowdowns, geopolitical conflict, or (as the case in 2020) global diseases like COVID-19. We first consider an oil demand reduction of 2.5% relative to the baseline (~1.8 million barrels per day (MMbbl d−1)), which we call small shock scenario. Then, we consider a reduction of ~5% (~3.6 MMbbl d−1), which we call COVID-19 pandemic scenario due to its resemblance with the contraction in oil demand observed during the 2020 pandemic19,20. Finally, we consider a reduction of ~10% (~7.1 MMbbl d−1), which we call medium shock. The latter could result from a vigorous adoption of alternatives or major macroeconomic downturns like a global financial recession. Note that in medium and large demand reduction scenarios (that is, roughly >5–10%), only the PC-SP is informative. In the other two cases (that is, oligopoly and cartel), the estimated SP is likely to become uninformative, since the market power correction term would change due to a transformation of the market structure (for example, countries leave/join OPEC, different propensity of countries to respect OPEC quotas, or different outcomes of the game-in-quantities played among oligopolists).

Table 2 characterizes the small, COVID-19, and medium shock scenarios using the different market structures. In PC, the marginal fields are mostly small producers, with median production of ~8,000–10,000 bbl d−1. The oligopoly and cartel cases shift few large conventional producers close to the industry margins (Table 2, and bar widths in Supplementary Figs. 12–14). The shift occurs for the same reasons explained above. Namely, oligopolists and members of the cartel adjust production from profitable fields to maximize their total profit.

Table 2 Characteristics of small and COVID-19 shock scenarios for crude oil demand reduction using different economic models

In all three economic models, the VWA MC of the marginal fields is much higher (25–375%) than the global average MC of ~US$5.6 bbl−1. Shifting low carbon intensive light and medium conventional fields towards the margin lowers the average CI of the displaced oil, but several heavy fields stay at the margin. We conclude that oil demand shocks result in nonlinear carbon emissions reduction. In all three economic cases, the CI of the crudes displaced by the small shock is ~25–54% larger than the global average of 51.9 kgCO2e bbl−1. The CI of the displaced crudes by COVID-19 shock is ~35% larger than the global average for PC, but is close to the global average CI using oligopolistic and cartel competition. The PC model still provides accurate estimates for 10% reduction shock where the CI of the displaced crudes is ~37% larger than the global average. However, the oligopoly and cartel models might not capture the market behaviour for such a large shock. The average CIs for these two economic cases due to 10% demand reduction are lower than global average with large volume share of light and medium crudes being displaced due to market power considerations.

The demand reduction magnitude affects the average CI of displaced crudes. Heavy oilfields with high CI (mostly located in Venezuela) have consistent contribution in all demand reduction scenarios and across all economic models. The total share of unconventional crudes (by volume) generally decreases by including market power corrections in the economic model, as it becomes more viable for large national oil companies to exert market power by reducing production from productive conventional fields. Our results show that given the proposed three economic cases, the small, COVID-19 and 10% reduction shocks in the global oil demand would result in the elimination of 39–54, 61–92 and 109–184 MtCO2e per year of upstream emissions, respectively. Supplementary Figure 15 shows a full range of annual carbon mitigation potential versus the amount of oil displaced using the three economic models. Larger reductions of GHG emissions associated with refining of oil and the final combustion of corresponding products would also occur, but are not included in these calculations. See Supplementary Information section 4.2 and Supplementary Table 8 for well-to-wheel mitigation potential estimate ranges and further discussions on demand sector GHG emissions.

In this work, we only included the production economics and identified the extensive margin of the oil industry. However, various other dynamic forces such as production agreements, region-specific fiscal regimes, regulations (for example, fuel standard policies), geopolitics (for example, sanctions, trade wars), technical advances and incidental events could move a particular oilfield toward or away from the margin. Further analysis of these factors is beyond the scope of this work, but could be pursued in future research (see Supplementary Information section 5).

Methods

Research scope

This work covers upstream emissions (including production and transport of crude oil to refinery gate) and costs. Due to lack of access to refinery cost data, we cannot generate a fully market-informed (consequential) well-to-wheel emissions analysis that goes all the way to refined fuels. Nevertheless, we provide a discussion on how upstream displacement could affect the emissions of the demand side (see Supplementary Information section 4.2).

Carbon intensity model

The field-level CI is estimated using the Oil Production Greenhouse Gas Emissions Estimator (OPGEE version 2.0)21,22,23. OPGEE is an open-source, peer-reviewed9,10,21,24,25,26,27,28,29,30,31, bottom-up, engineering-based model. The OPGEE system boundary is ‘well-to-refinery’ (WTR, that is, exploration, drilling and development, production and extraction, surface processing, maintenance, waste disposal, and crude transport to the refinery). Reported emissions are measured in gCO2e emitted per 1 MJ lower heating value (LHV) of crude petroleum delivered to the refinery entrance gate. All GHGs are converted to gCO2e using AR5 GWP100 conversion factors (without carbon feedback)32. See the OPGEE user guide21 for more details of each process stage.

OPGEE estimates CI using up to 50 parameters as input data for each modelled oilfield. If input data are not available for some parameters (common), OPGEE supplies defaults based on statistical analysis of petroleum engineering literature and commercial data sources (for example Oil & Gas Journal (O&GJ)33) enabling the software to estimate a field’s CI without complete data21,33.

In this work, field exploration, and drilling and development emissions are excluded from CIs reported in prior work1 to estimate GHG emissions associated with production of the next barrel of crude oil (that is, marginal upstream CIs). These two sectors hold a very low share of the total upstream GHG emissions (see supplementary Fig. S20 of ref. 1).

Global oilfields

In the previous work1, CIs were estimated for 8,966 global active oilfields (so-called child fields) supplying 78.9 million barrels per day (MMbbl d−1), and capturing ~98% of 2015 global crude oil and condensate production34. A combination of government reported data (Norway35,36, Canada37,38,39,40, Denmark41, UK42, Nigeria43, and US California44, US Alaska45 and US shale oils46), public literature (total of nearly 800 sources) and proprietary/commercial data sources (O&GJ 2015 survey33 and Wood Mackenzie (WM) oilfield datasets47) were used as input data1. Government and public literature data were collected and used for 1,009 global fields, accounting for about 64.3% of global crude oil production. Commercial data are utilized for the remainder (mostly small fields). We select 2015 as the reference year due to lags in some data sources. See our previous study supplementary materials document1 for further details.

Economic model

We frame our economic model as a profit-maximization problem. We study three different cases described here heuristically with mathematical details presented in the Supplementary Information. In the perfect competition (PC) case, every field is an independent firm which exerts no market power. In this context, the field management solves the profit-maximization problem taking the oil price as given. In the oligopolistic competition (oligopoly) case, a limited number of firms owns many fields. In this context, the field management solves the profit-maximization problem knowing that the quantity of oil produced by the firm who owns the field as well as its competitors influences the oil price. In the cartel competition (cartel) case, a limited number of firms coordinate their production decisions via a syndicate. In this context, the field management solves the profit-maximization problem knowing that the quantity of oil produced by the members of the syndicate influences the oil price. Said differently, in the oligopoly case a small number of oligopolistic competitors play a game-in-quantities. In the cartel case, a few firms work together to coordinate their production decisions around a union. In our model, the members of the cartel are the national oil companies associated with OPEC. Due to the complexities in modelling the realities of cartel dynamics, our cartel case assumes that the cartel operates in unison. The effect of a cartel with imperfect coordination would fall somewhere between individual company market power (oligopoly case) and the perfect cartel (cartel case).

In the PC case, field profits are the difference between field revenues and field costs, which we divide into two macro-classes: (1) costs to extract the oil (extraction costs) and (2) costs to discover new oil (exploration costs),

$${\rm{Profits}}=({\rm{oil\; price}}\times {\rm{volumes\; of\; oil\; extracted}})-{\rm{extraction\; costs}}-{\rm{exploration\; costs}}.$$

In the oligopoly and cartel cases, the field profits are the same. However, in the oligopoly case the management takes into consideration the effect of the volumes of oil produced by the firm who owns the field on the oil price, while in the cartel case the management takes into consideration the effect of the volumes of oil produce by the cartel on the oil price.

In all three cases, the decision choices are: what volume of oil to extract and how much money to spend in exploration48,49. While making these decisions the management faces two physical constraints. First, the quantity of reserves available at time t equals the reserves at time t − 1 minus the volumes of oil extracted at time t plus the quantity of oil discovered at time t. Second, the cumulative discoveries at time t equals the cumulative discoveries until time t − 1 plus the discoveries at time t.

The first-order condition of the optimization problem with respect to the volumes of oil extracted identifies how much money a producer is willing to spend to manage one extra barrel of oil. This value is called shadow price (of discovered oil),

$${\rm{Shadow\; price}}={\rm{oil\; price}}-{\rm{marginal\; extraction\; cost}}+{\rm{market\; power\; correction\; term}}.$$

The shadow price (SP) equals the difference between the oil price and the marginal extraction cost (MC)50 (that is, the cost of extracting the next barrel; this quantity is obtained by taking the first-order derivative of the extraction costs with respect to volumes of oil extracted) readjusted by a market power correction term.

If every field is an independent firm with no capacity to influence price (that is, PC), the market power correction term shrinks to zero and the SP becomes the difference between the oil price and the MC. For example, if a field sells its output at US$50 bbl−1 and its MC is US$40 bbl−1, the owner of the field is willing to spend (up to) US$10 to manage one more barrel located in that particular deposit. In the case of oligopolistic competition/perfect collusion behaviour, the SP takes into account the capacity of the firm/cartel to influence the global (average) oil price rescaled by the propensity of consumers to decrease the quantity of oil consumed due to an increase in oil price. Section 1 of the Supplementary Information provides the mathematical details of the economic framework linking the concept of SP to standard oil economics.

As the SP of a field approaches zero, the management problem shifts from ‘how much should I produce?’ (intensive margin choice) to ‘should I produce or not?’ (extensive margin choice). In other words, the fields with a SP close to zero identify the extensive margin of the oil industry. The emissions of this portion of the industry are the most sensitive to a drop in oil price caused by a reduction in the transportation fuel demand.

Note that estimating field-level gross profit was the main aim of this work, not the net profit. The gross profit is a better representative of fields’ geological and physical characteristics and production practices, whereas the net profit includes additional fiscal regimes (that is, royalties, severance taxes, income taxes, production sharing and so on), which are complex, country/region-specific and subject to change. Incorporating these fiscal terms is out of the capacity and the scope of the presented work.

Econometric analysis

All three variables making up SP are unobserved. To estimate them, we face three econometric problems: (1) the non-stationary nature of oil prices, (2) the endogenous link between costs, quantities and reserves, and (3) the uncertainty about the magnitude of the oil demand elasticity.

We do not know the price at which a field sells its output because we do not have access to commercial agreements between oil producers and oil refiners. However, we know the prices of publicly traded oil classes. More precisely, we know the landed costs of imported crudes in the United States from 1979 to 201851, as well as some key physical and chemical characteristics of every traded class52 (see Supplementary Fig. 1 and Supplementary Table 1. In the same way, we know the average price at which US refineries buy imported crudes53 and the average physical and chemical characteristics of crudes imported in the United States54. The physical and chemical characteristics most important to refineries are the crude density (measured as API gravity) and the sulfur content (measured as wt% sulfur).

We regress the difference between the price of a particular oil class and the average price at which refineries buy imported crudes on the differences between the API gravity of the oil class and the average API gravity of imported crudes as well as on the difference between the sulfur content of the oil class and the average sulfur content of imported crudes55,56,57. In doing so, we solve the non-stationarity problem while assuming that the difference between the price of a particular oil class and the average one is a linear function of the oil’s characteristics. We allow these linear deviations to be time-specific to adjust for changing in demand of transportation fuels as well as for technological change within the refinery sector. For example, in 2015 the average oil price was US$50.39 bbl−1, its API gravity 31.46, and its sulfur content 1.40%. In 2015 increasing the API gravity by one degree increased the value of a crude stream by US$0.13 bbl−1, while increasing sulfur content by 1% lowered the value of a crude stream by US$2.86 bbl−1. In 2016, these two quantities were +US$0.03 bbl−1 and −US$0.85 bbl−1. This change could be due to (1) a modification in the composition of the demand for transportation fuels (for example, more demand for gasoline, less demand for diesel), (2) a change in the technologies employed by US refineries, and (3) a combination of (1) and (2). Our econometric model is flexible enough to take into account all three possibilities (see Supplementary Information section 2.1).

We can use the two structural coefficients, which weight the impact of API gravity and sulfur content, to estimate field-level selling prices (see Supplementary Information section 2.1, equation 8). Using the API gravity and sulfur content reported in the 2018 WM dataset47, we estimate the selling price of 1,933 ‘parent project’ fields over the decade 2009–2018, thereby obtaining 1,933 × 10 = 19,330 simulated selling prices (see Supplementary Information section 2.1 for a detailed discussion on the results). See Supplementary Figs. 2 and 3 for a cross-sectional snapshot.

Next, we estimate the MC. An accurate measurement of MC is complicated because it is difficult to determine which factors of production are fixed and which are variable. However, the use of detailed accounting data, combined with standard econometric techniques, allows us to have a good first-order approximation of the MC of different types of fields. We use the WM dataset to obtain yearly cost data for the same 1,933 fields over the time interval 2009–2018. Then, we obtain the extraction costs summing the operational expenditures (OPEX), which include consumable inputs, labour, maintenance, repairs, accounting costs, license fees, office expenses, utilities and insurance. We also include capital expenditures not linked to exploration activities (non-exploration CAPEX, which include installation, acquisition, upgrading and restoring of the physical assets used to extract the oil).

After computing the extraction costs, we regress them against the volumes of oil extracted while controlling for the depletion level of the field, the geological characteristics of the field, and technological trends in the broader oil industry58. We estimate the structural coefficients of the cost function re-expressing the regression in first differences. The combination of the longitudinal structure of the dataset with the first-difference estimation method allows us to attenuate (or in the best case scenario to solve) eventual endogeneity problems59. The first-order derivative of the fit returns the estimated MC. Section 2.3 of Supplementary Information provides all the econometric details.

Finally, for two of the three cases analysed, we compute the market power correction term. Its expression is the same in both cases. Namely, the capacity of the firm/cartel to influence the average oil price rescaled by the capacity of consumers to lower their demand for oil-derived products when their prices increase. Said differently, the market power correction term adjusts the SP of every field by capturing the effect of a unit increase in the production of a specific field on the equilibrium oil price and, in turn, on the firm’s profits. Higher market power—corresponding to larger firm size—implies, ceteris paribus, a lower shadow price, because the effect of a fall in price due to the production of an extra unit of crude on the firm total revenues is proportional to the total production. For instance, if the production of an extra barrel causes the oil price to fall by 0.01 cents, then the firm must trade-off the profits generated by selling that extra barrel and a loss of 0.01 cents per barrel times the total number of barrels produced by the firm. Thus, accounting for market power makes the marginal unit produced by each firm/cartel less valuable, resulting in lower SPs. This effect is increasing in the firm/cartel size. Since the magnitude of the oil demand elasticity is object of econometric debate60, we validate our results using different point estimates within the interval −0.20 up to −0.35.

Data matching and coverage

The previous work on the CI of global oilfields1 is provided at a child field level. Child fields are individual discoveries that are part of a parent project. Parent fields are combinations of geologic deposits collected for the purposes of a combined valuation. The linkage with the economic data, available only at parent level, requires us to match the child field CIs1 to parent fields. The majority of the child non-technical oilfields from WM datasets47 (accessed 2018)—whose corresponding parent fields are available—directly matched with the OPGEE global dataset. We paired the remaining with smart string search and string distance matching using R as well as manual matching for the countries with poor total production coverage. Finally, we conduct an additional treatment on two important global producers (Canada and United States) based on the available data (see Supplementary Information section 2.2).

After the matching process is completed, we examine the representativeness of our techno-economic dataset. In total, we matched 1,933 parent fields located in 77 countries. Their combined production is ~71 MMbbl d−1 and it captures ~90% of the 2015 global crude oil and condensate production34. Supplementary Table 5 returns the coverage summary of the top 20 largest global producers, and Supplementary Fig. 4 zooms in on the geographic location and the CI of the mapped fields.