Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter May 23, 2023

Wealth Inequality and the Exploration of Novel Technologies

  • Alessandro Spiganti ORCID logo EMAIL logo

Abstract

I investigate whether wealth inequality hinders the discovery of novel technologies in a competitive screening model. Agents can engage in exploration, which may lead to the discovery of superior technologies, but it is likely to waste time with inferior ones. Talented agents are better at weeding out inferior technologies, but talent is unobservable by lenders. When agents are poor, this causes an adverse selection problem whereby exploration is pursued by untalented agents rather than by talented ones. As economies become wealthier, the misallocation problem of talented agents weakens. Higher inequality worsens this misallocation problem when the economy is wealthy, but can increase efficiency in poor economies.

JEL Classification: D53; D82; O31

Corresponding author: Alessandro Spiganti, Ca’ Foscari University of Venice, Department of Economics, Cannaregio 873, 30121 Venice, Italy, E-mail:

Thanks go to Catherine Bobtcheff, Andrew Clausen, Elena Lagomarsino, John Hardman Moore, Jonathan Thomas, and various conferences participants.


Award Identifier / Grant number: ES/J500136/1

  1. Research funding: This work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council [grant number ES/J500136/1].

Appendix A

A.1 A General Model

This section presents a comprehensive model where I add all the extensions considered in Section 5 to the baseline model of Section 3.

First, I add an outside option to entrepreneurship. I assume that at the beginning of the first period, agents can choose to become either investors or entrepreneurs. Investors deposit their wealth in a bank for a riskless return; conversely, an entrepreneur undertakes a risky investment in the form of starting a firm and can then choose to explore or exploit (as in the baseline model). Second, relatively to the baseline model, I assume that talented agents are not only better at weeding out inferior actions but also at discovery more productive actions. I assume that a proportion λ of agents is talented, which means that they can exert unobservable effort at a fixed and indivisible monetary cost e > 0 to increase both their unconditional probability of success using the novel approach to the level EpN,H, which is assumed to be in (EpN,L,pC), and their conditional probability of success to EpN,H|S,N, assumed to be in (EpN|S,N,1). For the remaining proportion 1 − λ (the untalented agents), the effort cost is prohibitively high. Third, I assume that banks can observe the wealth of a potential entrepreneur and the outcome of her firm, but effort and project selection are unobservable. Fourth, I consider the general equilibrium case, where the rate of return adjust to clear the credit market. Since the analytical results are more notation-intensive than the in baseline model, for ease of reading, I shorten the notation as follows: p C = p, EpN,H=qH, EpN,L=qL, EpN,H|S,N=qHS, and EpN|S,N=qHL.

The assumption of efficiency is that, absent the need for financing, the net presented value of a project run by a talented explorer is strictly greater than the net present value from exploitation and investment, both of which are strictly greater than the net present value from untalented exploration, i.e. Y H e > max{Y C , RI} > min{Y C , RI} > Y L . This implies that the equilibrium risk-free interest rate must be such that

RYLI;YHeIR̲;R̄

I do not take a stand on whether exploitation is preferred to investing in first best (this will depend on the equilibrium interest rate).

As in the baseline model, only three types of borrowers need to be considered: talented explorers (H), untalented explorers (L), and exploiters (C). I assume that agents choose to become investors if indifferent between becoming investors or entrepreneurs, and exploiters if indifferent between exploitation and exploration. The tie-breaking assumptions rule out mixed strategy equilibria. Thus, for a given wealth level and menu of contract, all talented agents make the same decision as each other, and all untalented agents make the same decision as each other. As a consequence, for any given wealth class, I only need to consider pair-wise combinations of exploration (with or without effort), exploitation, and investing. Equilibrium contracts can be of two types: pooling equilibrium, in which both types receive an identical contract, and separating equilibrium, in which contracts induce self-revelation of their unobservable ability.

Similarly to the baseline model, it cannot exist a zero-profit separating menu of contract that induces the two types to both enter exploration, since this cannot be incentive compatible. Hence, an equilibrium contract must be either a pooling contract or a separating contract that only one type accepts. There are three possible pooling contracts: one pooling effort-exerting explorers with untalented explorers σHL, one pooling effort-exerting explorers with untalented exploiters σHC, and one pooling shirking explorers with untalented explorers σL.[10] Each of these contracts must lie on the corresponding zero-profit condition, otherwise banks could undercut each other. These three putative contracts are then given by τHL(A,R)=R(IA)/q̄HL, τHC(A,R)=R(IA)/q̄HC, and τ L (A, R) = R(IA)/q L , where q̄HL=λqH+(1λ)qL and q̄HC=λqH+(1λ)p are the corresponding Bayesian probability of success of a random applicant.

I start by considering the putative contract pooling effort-exerting talented and untalented explorers. Let V(i, j, τ) be the expected payoff of an agent of realized talent i = {H, L} (i.e. talent after effort choice), choosing the project j = {N, C}, and under a repayment τ. This contract can be accepted by the untalented agent if the participation constraint, VL,N,τHL>RA, and the incentive compatibility constraint, VL,C,τHL<VL,N,τHL, are both satisfied. Solving these for A leads to

(A.13a)A<qLq̄HLqLI+qL+qLqLS+pqLpq̄HLR(q̄HLqL)Y=:ϕHL(R)
(A.13b)A<Ip+qLpqLqLqLSq̄HLR(pqL)Y=:ϕHLIC(R).

Likewise, consider the putative contract with both effort-exerting talented explorer and untalented exploiters. This contract can be offered to the untalented agent if the participation constraint, VL,C,τHC>RA, and incentive compatibility constraint (versus exploration), VL,C,τHC<VL,N,τHC, are satisfied. Equivalently,

(A.14a)A>ppq̄HCI2pq̄HCR(pq̄HC)Y=:ϕHC(R)
(A.14b)A>Ip+qLpqLqLqLSq̄HCR(pqL)Y=:ϕHCIC(R).

Imagine the bank offering both σHL and σHC. A low ability agent will prefer the former to the latter if

A<IpqLqLqLS+qLpq̄HLq̄HCλRqH(pqL)Y=:ϕNC(R).

The wealth levels ϕ HL , ϕ HC , ϕ NC , ϕHCIC, and ϕHLIC naturally divide the (R, A) space into twelve areas, as shown in Panel (a) of Figure A.1. In the areas (1)–(4), the low ability agent prefers investing to both pooling contracts, and thus a pooling contract is not offered in equilibrium. In the areas (5) and (6), the low ability agent prefers σHL to both investing and σHC. Since σHL is also incentive compatible, it can be offered. In area (7), L would like to be offered σHC but this is not incentive compatible; however, σHL is both incentive compatible and preferred to investing, and thus it can be offered. In areas (8)–(11), L prefers σHC to both σHL and investing, and it is incentive compatible. Finally, in area (12), L prefers σHC, which is not incentive compatible; however, σHL cannot be offered because L would prefer to become an investor (the equilibrium contract is derived below).

Figure A.1: 
Contracts offered.
Figure A.1:

Contracts offered.

The relevant conditions are summarized in Panel (b) of Figure A.1. In the area labelled “investing”, low ability agents prefer investing to accepting a pooling contract. In the blue area labelled “pooling (HC)”, the pooling contract that can be offered by banks is σHC; in the green area labelled “pooling (HL)”, the equilibrium pooling contract is σHL. In the remaining white area, a pooling contract cannot be offered, because σHC is not incentive compatible, whereas σHL does not satisfy the participation constraint.

When untalented agents prefer investing to any pooling contract, talented agents can be offered a separating contract. Given the assumption on efficiency, the only separating contract that I need to consider is the one inducing talented agents to become effort-exerting explorers. The first-best zero-profit exploration contract is τ H (A, R) = R(IA)/q H . An untalented agent with equal wealth A does not accept τ H if she prefers investing to exploring using this contract, VL,N,τHRA, and to exploiting using this same contract, VL,C,τHRA. Solving these two conditions for A results in

(A.15a)AqLqHqLI+qL+qLqLS+pqLpqHRqHqLY=:ϕI(R)
(A.15b)AppqHI2pqHR(pqH)Y=:ϕC(R).

In Figure A.2, I update Figure A.1(b) with the new threshold ϕ I (R).[11] This shows that for certain wealth and risk-free interest rate combinations, a separating exploration contract with effort is incentive compatible, as shown in the area labelled “separating”. I have also shown that there is an area where the only contract that can be offered is a pooling contract. In the area labelled “pooling (HC)”, the equilibrium pooling contract is the one pooling effort-exerting explorers with exploiters; in the area labelled “pooling (HL)”, the equilibrium pooling contract is the exploration one.

Figure A.2: 
Separating and pooling contracts.
Figure A.2:

Separating and pooling contracts.

I still need to determine which contract is offered in the area between ϕ HL , ϕ I , and ϕHCIC. The separating exploration contract requiring effort is not incentive compatible, as it is also accepted by low ability agents, but a pooling contract cannot be offered. To graphically show the equilibrium for these wealth class, it will prove useful to consider also possible repayments in case of failure τF; note that these be negative, given the limited liability assumption. This is represented in Panel (a) of Figure A.3, where R and A have been chosen so that in the first panel we are in the white area on the left of ϕ HC , while on the second panel we are in the white area on the right of ϕ HC from of Figure A.2.[12] The pooling contract cannot be offered either because low ability agent prefers investing to both pooling contracts (second panel), or because the pooling exploration contract does not satisfy the participation constraint while the exploitation and exploration pooling contract is not incentive compatible (first panel).[13] In both cases, however, the banks can offer a separating pair of contracts, like yL,yH. Effort-exerting high ability agents strictly prefer y H ,[14] while low ability agents are indifferent among y L , y H , and investing: thus, they choose to become investors by assumption. This is a Bertrand-Nash equilibrium where banks make positive profits, since no profitable deviations are available.[15]

Figure A.3: 
Contracts offered.
Figure A.3:

Contracts offered.

What are the terms of the profitable separating menu of contract? From Panel (a) of Figure A.3, the contract offered to the low ability agent (when neither the zero-profit separating contract nor a pooling contract can be offered) is given by the intersection of V(L, N, τ ) = RA and the zero-profit condition from a pooling exploration contract. Solving the corresponding system of equations,

YqL+qLqLS+pqLpqLτS1qLτF=RAτS=RIAq̄HL1q̄HLq̄HLτF,

reveals that the contract offered to the low ability agent, y L , is

yL(A,R)=R1qLq̄HLqLIqL+qLqLS+pqLp(1qL)q̄HLqLYRARqLq̄HLqLI+qL+qLqLS+pqLpq̄HLq̄HLqLYRAT.

The terms of the contract offered to the high ability agents, y H , are derived by the intersection of V(L, N, τ ) = RA with the vertical axis, τF = 0, i.e.

yH(A,R)=YqL+qLqLS+pqLpRAqL0.

The high ability agent’s expected utility associated with this contract is

(A.16)YqH+qHqHS+pqHpqHqLYqL+qLqLS+pqLpRA.

The assumption on efficiency ensures that high ability agents prefer this contract to investing. Setting (A.16) equal to YqH+qHqHS+pqHpR̂qHIA and solving for R̂ reveals that the interest rate on this contract is

R̂=YqH+qHqHS+pqHpRAqLIA.

This completes the set of contracts offered by the banks, as summarised in Panel (b) of Figure A.3.

I now consider the agent’s decision given that banks offer one of the pooling contracts above. An untalented individual with wealth A has three options: she can become an investor, she can become an exploiter, or she can become an explorer. Panel (b) of Figure A.1 above gave us the preferred option for each R and A combination.

Likewise, a talented individual with wealth A has four options: (a) she can become an investor, (b) she can become an exploiter, (c) she can become a shirking explorer, or (d) she can become an explorer who exerts effort. By the assumption on efficiency, effortful exploration is always preferred to exploitation, and pooling with low ability exploiters is always preferred to investing.[16] A shirking high ability agent is no different from a low ability agent, and thus the analysis is the same as above. In addition to those conditions, effortful exploration is preferred to shirking if

(A.17a)AIq̄HLr(qHqL)qHqHSqLqLS+(1p)(qHqL)Ye=:ϕHLH(R)
(A.17b)AIq̄HCr(qHqL)qHqHSqLqLS+(1p)(qHqL)Ye=:ϕHCH(R)

and to investing if

(A.18)A>qHqHq̄HLIq̄HLr(qHq̄HL)qH+qHqHS+pqHpYe=:ϕIH(R).

Panel (a) of Figure A.4 summarises all participation and incentive compatibility constraints in the (R, A) space. This allows us to complement the analysis regarding the banks’ problem by adding the decisions of the agents.

Figure A.4: 
Occupational choices. INV stands for investing, C for setting up a conventional firm, N for untalented exploration, and NE for effortful exploration.
Figure A.4:

Occupational choices. INV stands for investing, C for setting up a conventional firm, N for untalented exploration, and NE for effortful exploration.

In the areas (1)–(9), banks offer the zero-profit separating exploration contract to high ability agents, high ability agents accept it and exert effort, whereas low ability agents prefer investing. In the areas (10)–(16), the profitable separating exploration contract is offered, high ability agents accept it and exert effort, whereas low ability agents become investors. In the areas (17)–(18), only the pooling exploration contract can be offered, but this does not satisfy the participation constraint of the high ability agents, who thus decide to become investors. Low ability agents do not explore because they would be identified as low ability, and thus they prefer to invest. In the areas (19)–(21), the pooling exploration contract is offered, but high ability agents do not exert effort. Therefore, they are no different from low ability agents and bank, to break even, must ask for the interest rate consistent with the low ability applicants. Thus, all agents prefer to invest. In the areas (22)–(25), the pooling exploration contract is offered, high ability agents exert effort and low ability agents become explorers. In the areas (26)–(34), the exploitation and exploration pooling contract is offered, high ability agents exert effort and low ability agents become exploiters.

These insights are summarised in Panel (b) of Figure A.4. In the yellow area, the zero-profit separating exploration contract is offered by the banks, high ability agents accept it and exert effort, whereas low ability agents become investors. Similarly, in the red area, low ability agents become investors, and high ability agents become effort-exerting explorers, but banks make positive profits. In the grey area, only the pooling exploration contract can be offered, but high ability agents do not become explorers either because they do not want to (light-grey area), or because they are unwilling to provide effort (dark-grey area): everyone would be treated as a low ability agent by the banks, and thus all agents prefer to become investors given the efficiency assumption. In the green area, the pooling exploration contract is offered, high ability agents provide effort and low ability agents become explorers. Finally, in the blue area, low ability agents become exploiters and high ability agents become effort-exerting explorers, thanks to the pooling exploration and exploitation contract.

Figure A.5 shows the possible general equilibria that could ensue. Up to the risk-free interest rate R1 (defined by ϕHL=ϕHCIC), there are only three wealth classes: a lower-class where everyone become an investor, a (lower) middle-class where high ability agents exert effort and cross-subsidise low ability explorers, and an upper-class where low ability agents become exploiters who cross-subsidise the high ability effort-exerting explorers. Since ϕHLH is strictly increasing in R, the number of entrepreneurs decreases as the risk-free interest rate increases in [R, R1].

Figure A.5: 
General equilibrium.
Figure A.5:

General equilibrium.

Between R1 and R2 (defined by ϕI=ϕHCIC), we have four wealth classes, since (part of) the upper middle-class shows up, where low ability agents become investors and banks make positive profits on the effortful exploration contract accepted by the high ability agents. The number of entrepreneurs is strictly decreasing in the interest rate both because ϕHLH is strictly increasing in R and because the richest low ability agents (that were previously lower middle-class and are now middle middle-class) switch from entrepreneurship to investing.

Consider a rental rate R2 and R3 (defined by ϕHC=ϕHCIC). The number of entrepreneurs is still strictly decreasing in R since ϕHLH is strictly increasing in R (and thus agents move from the lower middle-class to the lower-class where they become investors), ϕ HL is strictly decreasing in R (more and more agents move from the lower middle-class to the middle middle-class where low ability agents become investors), and ϕHCIC is strictly increasing in R (the upper-class shrinks in favour of the newly formed upper middle-class, and thus the poorest low ability agents of the upper-class move from non-innovative entrepreneurship to investing). For rates between R3 and R4 (defined by ϕHL=ϕHLH), the case is similar to the previous one, with the difference that ϕ HC is steeper than ϕHCIC and thus the number of entrepreneurs decreases even faster as R increases.

For rates between R4 and R5 (defined by ϕ HC = I), the lower middle-class disappears. Since ϕ HL is strictly decreasing in r, the richest members of the lower-class start entering the (upper) middle-class, and thus the number of entrepreneurs increases. However, since ϕ HC is strictly increasing in r, the poorest members of the upper-class enter the upper middle-class, pushing the number of entrepreneurs down. Which of these two effects dominates depends on the wealth distribution.

Finally, for rates above R5, the upper-class disappears. The number of entrepreneurs is strictly increasing in R as the lower-class shrinks.

To summarise, the number of entrepreneurs is strictly decreasing in R up to R4, it is potentially non-monotonic between R4 and R5, and strictly increasing above R5. Thus, depending on the wealth distribution (and parameters), we could have multiple equilibria. If we restrict our attention to rates below R4, the equilibrium, if it exists, is unique.

Numerical simulations for this extended model are available on request.

A.2 Wealth Transition Equations

Agents in the first generation are endowed with warm-glow Cobb–Douglas utility functions, which imply that they optimally bequeath a fraction δ of their end-of-life wealth. In turn, this will result in the distribution of endowment G(A) of the second generation. Moreover, agents are risk-neutral, which means that they want to maximize end-of-life wealth. As a consequence, the model for the first generation is qualitatively the same as the one in the baseline model, which means that the static equilibrium is the same.

Let i ∈ [0, 1] indicate a lineage of agents; moreover, I add the subscript f to indicate the corresponding variable or parameter for the first-period generation, when needed. Given the occupational choices of the first generation and the assumption that types are intergenerationally uncorrelated, the wealth transition equations for any lineage i are thus given by

Ai=δYCfRIfAifif Aif<Aef;Ai=δYHfEpN,HfRIfAifρN̄f,λδYLfEpN,LfRIfAifρN̄f,1λif AifAef,ALf;Ai=δYHfσ9f,λδYCfσ10f,1λif AifALf,AHHf;Ai=δYHfRIfAif,λδYCfRIfAif,1λif AifAHHf,If,

where σ9f and σ10f are the profitable separating exploration and negative-profit exploitation contracts offered to agents with wealth between ALf,AHHf and represented in Panel (b) of Figure 2.

References

Acemoglu, D., and F. Zilibotti. 1999. “Information Accumulation in Development.” Journal of Economic Growth 4: 5–38. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1009833807671.10.1023/A:1009833807671Search in Google Scholar

Aghion, P., and P. Bolton. 1997. “A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Development.” The Review of Economic Studies 64: 151–72. https://doi.org/10.2307/2971707.Search in Google Scholar

Akerlof, G. A. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality, Uncertainty, and the Market Mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488–500. https://doi.org/10.2307/1879431.Search in Google Scholar

Andreoni, J. 1989. “Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence.” Journal of Political Economy 97: 1447–58. https://doi.org/10.1086/261662.Search in Google Scholar

Atkinson, A. B. 1970. “On the Measurement of Inequality.” Journal of Economic Theory 2: 244–63. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(70)90039-6.Search in Google Scholar

Banerjee, A. V., and A. F. Newman. 1993. “Occupational Choice and the Process of Development.” Journal of Political Economy 101: 274–98. https://doi.org/10.1086/261876.Search in Google Scholar

Bergemann, D., and U. Hege. 1998. “Venture Capital Financing, Moral Hazard, and Learning.” Journal of Banking & Finance 22: 703–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0378-4266(98)00017-x.Search in Google Scholar

Bergemann, D., and U. Hege. 2005. “The Financing of Innovation: Learning and Stopping.” The RAND Journal of Economics 36: 719–52.Search in Google Scholar

Bouvard, M. 2014. “Real Option Financing under Asymmetric Information.” Review of Financial Studies 27: 180–210. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhs068.Search in Google Scholar

Chemla, G., and K. Tinn. 2020. “Learning through Crowdfunding.” Management Science 66: 1783–801. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2018.3278.Search in Google Scholar

Coco, G., and G. Pignataro. 2014. “The Poor are Twice Cursed: Wealth Inequality and Inefficient Credit Market.” Journal of Banking & Finance 49: 149–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.09.002.Search in Google Scholar

DeMeza, D., and D. Webb. 1987. “Too Much Investment: A Problem of Asymmetric Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102: 281–92. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885064.Search in Google Scholar

Drugov, M., and R. Macchiavello. 2014. “Financing Experimentation.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6: 315–49. https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.6.1.315.Search in Google Scholar

Ewens, M., R. Nanda, and M. Rhodes-Kropf. 2018. “Cost of Experimentation and the Evolution of Venture Capital.” Journal of Financial Economics 128: 422–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.03.001.Search in Google Scholar

Galor, O., and J. Zeira. 1993. “Income Distribution and Macroeconomics.” The Review of Economic Studies 60: 35–52. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297811.Search in Google Scholar

Ghatak, M., M. Morelli, and T. Sjöström. 2007. “Entrepreneurial Talent, Occupational Choice, and Trickle up Policies.” Journal of Economic Theory 137: 27–48. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2006.02.007.Search in Google Scholar

Gomes, R., D. Gottlieb, and L. Maestri. 2016. “Experimentation and Project Selection: Screening and Learning.” Games and Economic Behavior 96: 145–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2016.02.001.Search in Google Scholar

Grüner, H. P. 2003. “Redistribution as a Selection Device.” Journal of Economic Theory 108: 194–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-0531(02)00015-7.Search in Google Scholar

Halac, M., N. Kartik, and Q. Liu. 2016. “Optimal Contracts for Experimentation.” The Review of Economic Studies 83: 1040–91. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdw013.Search in Google Scholar

Hellwig, M. 1987. “Some Recent Developments in the Theory of Competition in Markets with Adverse Selection.” European Economic Review 31: 319–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(87)90046-8.Search in Google Scholar

Hörner, J., and L. Samuelson. 2013. “Incentives for Experimenting Agents.” The RAND Journal of Economics 44: 632–63. https://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12039.Search in Google Scholar

Inci, E. 2013. “Occupational Choice and the Quality of Entrepreneurs.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 92: 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2013.04.015.Search in Google Scholar

Jaimovich, E. 2011. “Sectoral Differentiation, Allocation of Talent, and Financial Development.” Journal of Development Economics 96: 47–60. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.07.005.Search in Google Scholar

Klein, N. 2016. “The Importance of Being Honest.” Theoretical Economics 11: 773–811. https://doi.org/10.3982/te1913.Search in Google Scholar

Kreps, D., and J. Sobel. 1994. “Signalling.” In Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications, ed. 2. edited by R. Aumann, and S. Hart, 849–67. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0005(05)80057-8Search in Google Scholar

Legros, P., A. F. Newman, and E. Proto. 2014. “Smithian Growth through Creative Organization.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 96: 796–811. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00421.Search in Google Scholar

Manso, G. 2011. “Motivating Innovation.” The Journal of Finance 66: 1823–60. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01688.x.Search in Google Scholar

Martin, A. 2009. “A Model of Collateral, Investment, and Adverse Selection.” Journal of Economic Theory 4: 1572–88. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2009.01.004.Search in Google Scholar

Meh, C. A. 2005. “Entrepreneurship, Wealth Inequality, and Taxation.” Review of Economic Dynamics 8: 688–719. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2005.03.001.Search in Google Scholar

Murphy, K. M., A. Shleifer, and R. L. Vishny. 1989. “Income Distribution, Market Size, and Industrialization.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104: 537–64. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937810.Search in Google Scholar

Podder, N., and N. C. Kakwani. 1976. “Distribution of Wealth in Australia.” Review of Income and Wealth 22: 75–92. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4991.1976.tb01143.x.Search in Google Scholar

Riley, J. G. 1979. “Informational Equilibrium.” Econometrica 47: 331–59. https://doi.org/10.2307/1914187.Search in Google Scholar

Rothschild, M., and J. Stiglitz. 1970. “Increasing Risk I: A Definition.” Journal of Economic Theory 2: 225–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(70)90038-4.Search in Google Scholar

Rothschild, M., and J. Stiglitz. 1976. “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90: 629–49. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885326.Search in Google Scholar

Spiganti, A. 2020a. “Can Starving Start-Ups Beat Fat Labs? A Bandit Model of Innovation with Endogenous Financing Constraint.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 122: 702–31. https://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12333.Search in Google Scholar

Spiganti, A. 2020b. “Inequality of Opportunity, Inequality of Effort, and Innovation.” In EUI Working Paper 2020/02.Search in Google Scholar

Thurow, L. C. 1970. “Analyzing the American Income Distribution.” The American Economic Review 60: 261–9.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M. 1979. “Optimal Search for the Best Alternative.” Econometrica 47: 641–54. https://doi.org/10.2307/1910412.Search in Google Scholar

Wilson, C. 1977. “A Model of Insurance Markets with Incomplete Information.” Journal of Economic Theory 16: 167–207. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(77)90004-7.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2022-04-19
Accepted: 2023-05-08
Published Online: 2023-05-23

© 2023 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 3.5.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2022-0073/html
Scroll to top button